




版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡介
1、Table of contents HYPERLINK l _bookmark0 Introduction 2 HYPERLINK l _bookmark1 R&I and growth 2 HYPERLINK l _bookmark2 Main features of R&I 2 HYPERLINK l _bookmark6 Main enablers for R&I creation, adoption and diffusion 4 HYPERLINK l _bookmark7 Size of the market 4 HYPERLINK l _bookmark9 Competition
2、 and intellectual property right protection 5 HYPERLINK l _bookmark10 Human capital 5 HYPERLINK l _bookmark11 Financing of R&I 6 HYPERLINK l _bookmark12 Evidence on rates of return from R&I 6 HYPERLINK l _bookmark13 R&I policies 7 HYPERLINK l _bookmark14 The case for R&I policies: market failure 7 H
3、YPERLINK l _bookmark16 R&I policies: why it may not work: government failure 9 HYPERLINK l _bookmark18 The R&I policy toolkit 10 HYPERLINK l _bookmark19 R&I tax incentives 10 HYPERLINK l _bookmark20 Direct subsidies 11 HYPERLINK l _bookmark21 Loans and public venture capital 11 HYPERLINK l _bookmark
4、22 Public R&I and public-private partnerships 12 HYPERLINK l _bookmark23 Public procurement 12 HYPERLINK l _bookmark24 Patents 12 HYPERLINK l _bookmark26 Regulations 13 HYPERLINK l _bookmark27 Main R&I policies deployed in the EU 13 HYPERLINK l _bookmark28 R&I policy at the EU: Framework Programmes
5、13 HYPERLINK l _bookmark32 Major R&I Policy instruments at the EU and its Member States 15 HYPERLINK l _bookmark34 R&I policies and growth 20 HYPERLINK l _bookmark35 R&I policies: do they work to stimulate private R&I? Evidence from evaluations at the micro HYPERLINK l _bookmark35 level 20 HYPERLINK
6、 l _bookmark36 R&I tax incentives 20 HYPERLINK l _bookmark39 Direct subsidies 22 HYPERLINK l _bookmark40 The R&I Policy Toolkit 23 HYPERLINK l _bookmark41 R&I (policies) and their effect on (productivity) growth: evidence from macro-models 24 HYPERLINK l _bookmark44 NEMESIS 25 HYPERLINK l _bookmark4
7、5 QUEST III 27 HYPERLINK l _bookmark47 Conclusions and further steps 30 HYPERLINK l _bookmark48 References 32IntroductionBefore research and innovation (R&I) policies can be identified as instruments for economic growth, and therefore of smart government spending, several questions must be answered.
8、 First: does R&I contribute to growth? At present, it is widely acknowledged that innovation is an important force behind long-run economic growth. In particular, models that use an endogenous growth framework make a strong case for the growth power from R&I and innovation (eg Aghion, 2006). But thi
9、s does not yet make the case for R&I policies. Will R&I policies lead to sufficient innovation and growth to cover the opportunity costs of using public funds for R&I?To address these questions, we have reviewed the evidence on the impact of R&I policies. We first looked at the evidence of the impac
10、t of public intervention on private R&I and innovation, which is mostly from micro-analysis. To assess the impact from public R&I on growth, we needed to complement micro-results with a macro-perspective. To this end, we looked at how R&I and R&I policies perform in affecting GDP growth and jobs in
11、the applied macro-models most commonly used in European Union policy analysis. We start with a brief description of the critical features and enablers of the R&I process needed to appropriately account for its role HYPERLINK l _bookmark3 1 in economic growth, as well as the main policies aimed at pr
12、omoting R&I to boost growth. A proper understanding of the features of R&I, and its enablers and policies, is important to be better able to use the appropriate models and data to evaluate the impact of R&I policies. We conclude with some recommendations for improving R&I policy assessment for growt
13、h.R&I and growthBased on the literature on R&I, this section describes and analyses the critical features of the innovation process needed to account for R&Is role in economic growth and welfare.Main features of R&ITechnological knowledge is the sum of techniques employed in the production of goods
14、and services. It results from the cumulative aggregation of new technological ideas or innovations, resulting from a systematic research and development (R&I) effort and benefiting from multiple forms of knowledge spillovers. R&I refers to those economic activities undertaken with the purpose of imp
15、roving the actual1 See also Veugelers (2016) and European Commission (2020b) for more on R&I policies and their impact on growth.state of technology. As for physical and human capital, R&I is a form of investment that cumulates in the stock of technological knowledge. The stock of technological know
16、ledge also relates to intangible capital, which includes computerised information, innovative property and economic competencies HYPERLINK l _bookmark4 2.Innovations represent additions to the stock of technological knowledge, and result from R&I activity. In the pioneering work of Romer (1990) and
17、Aghion and Howitt (1998), R&I activities are undertaken with the purpose of improving the actual state of technology, which in Romer (1990) takes the form a new product, and in the Schumpeterian framework a better-quality version of an existing product (see Aghion and Howitt, 1998).During the R&I st
18、age, researchers benefit from their past experience and are conditioned by their state of knowledge and their past technological choices. This is where path dependency or technological cumulativeness comes into the picture. To quote Dosi and Nelson (2010), “ advances are likely to occur in the neigh
19、bourhood of the techniques already in use within the firm.” Following Griliches (1979), one way of modelling the cumulative nature of R&I is to consider not the flow of R&I expenditure but the accumulated stock of past and present R&I expenditure as the appropriate variable to affect productivity, o
20、r to enter as an input in an extended production function. Learning-by- doing and learning-by-using are other important elements in knowledge building HYPERLINK l _bookmark5 3.In a world of open innovation, firms may collaborate in their research efforts, exploiting knowledge complementarities. Firm
21、s may also benefit from scientific progress, coming from universities or public research labs. Instead of searching themselves for new ideas, firms may prefer to acquire technological knowledge, in embodied or disembodied form, eg by licensing the latest technology.A specific feature of technologica
22、l knowledge is its non-rival nature: it can be used by many agents at the same time. In this sense, it entails high generation costs but can be easily reproduced. However, technological knowledge does not get transmitted as easily. First, technological knowledge is partially tacit, that is, it canno
23、t be entirely explained in a manual by means of words, symbols or graphs, as opposed to codified knowledge. Second, it is cumulative, meaning that it cannot be understood without grasping prior knowledge. Third, it cannot be assimilated, adopted and reproduced without incurring substantial costs rel
24、ated to building the needed absorptive capacity. It bears the cost of2 Corrado et al (2005, 2009) extended, in the context of the economic growth literature, the definition of a production technology to include the stock of intangible capital. They found for the United States that the growth rate of
25、 output per worker increases more rapidly when intangible capital is included, that capital deepening (on physical and intangible capital) becomes the unambiguously dominant source of growth, diminishing the role of total factor productivity, and that the labour income share has significantly decrea
26、sed over the last 50 years because of the rise of intangible capital.3 The role of learning-by-doing in the growth process was first studied by Arrow (1962).learning, adaptation and reproduction. Technological knowledge is therefore not a free good that falls like manna from heaven for economic acto
27、rs wishing to use it, but requires a deliberate effort on the part of the actors to generate, adopt and use it. In summary, the process of building technological knowledge can considerably benefit from knowledge spillovers. In order to benefit from R&I spillovers, firms have to develop their absorpt
28、ive capacity HYPERLINK l _bookmark8 4. The absorptive capacity of a firm positively depends on the accumulation of its previous R&I investments. It helps understanding why private R&I and knowledge spillovers are likely to be complements in the creation of new technologies.New technological ideas, a
29、fter discovery, diffuse throughout the economy by affecting the design of products and production processes of firms in different industrial sectors and geographical locations. This process is referred as the diffusion of new technologies. Extensive empirical work was undertaken by Comin et al (2008
30、) and Comin and Hobijn (2004, 2010), among others, describing the long process of diffusion of new technologies across time and countries. The diffusion of technologies can take place through the various mechanisms by which knowledge spills over across space and time: trade relationships, foreign di
31、rect investment, mergers and acquisitions, movement of personnel, patents, patent citations, publications, research collaborations and networks. A new product or process is more likely to be widely and/or more quickly adopted if it uses existing or familiar technologies, or if complementary goods or
32、 services already exist. It is not always the superior technology that gets adopted.Main enablers for R&I creation, adoption and diffusionSize of the marketFirms may be more willing to do R&I if there is a large market, enabling them to recover their R&I investment expenditure quickly. The market ca
33、n be national or international depending on the presence or not of trade and non-trade barriers. Acemoglu and Linn (2004) found for the pharmaceutical industry that potential market size had a major effect on the entry of non-generic drugs and new molecular entities.4 For Cohen and Levinthal (1990),
34、 absorptive capacity was the “firms ability to recognize the value of new, external information, assimilate it, and apply it to commercial ends.” In more precise terms, Leahy and Neary (2007) defined a firms absorptive capacity as “its ability to absorb spillovers from other firms.” Cohen and Levint
35、hal (1989) “suggest that R&I not only generates new information, but also enhances the firms ability to assimilate and exploit existing information.”Competition and intellectual property right protectionPatent systems grant temporary monopoly rights to innovators in order to protect them from being
36、copied or imitated. By restricting competition, the patent system aims at solving the market distortion generated by the non-rivalry feature of technological knowledge; patents are expected to promote innovation, restoring the incentives to innovate.Competition, however, can be beneficial to innovat
37、ion too, since in competitive environments firms innovate with the hope of escaping competition (see Aghion et al, 2001). This argument relates to the so-called replacement effect: entrant firms have more incentives to innovate than incumbents since innovation allows them to steal at least partially
38、 the monopoly rents of incumbents (Arrow, 1962). In an extreme case when the prospect of entry is very low, incumbents have little incentive to innovate. However, if there is a risk of their monopoly rents being stolen, incumbents innovate to escape competition from potential entrants. Competition m
39、ay also promote innovation through the type of market size effect described above, if it results in increasing the size of the market by lowering prices.Theoretical and empirical research has found that the relationship between competition and innovation follows an inverted U-shape. When competition
40、 is low, incumbents do not need to protect their monopoly rents, having little incentive to innovate (replacement effect). When markets become more competitive, incumbent firms innovate more to escape competition (escape competition effect). However, when there is too much competition, the gains fro
41、m innovation dilute to the point that neither incumbents nor potential entrants have incentives to innovate (Schumpeters argument). Aghion et al (2005) found strong evidence of an inverted U-shape relationship between product market competition and innovation, and developed an endogenous growth mode
42、l to understand this evidence. Aghion et al (2009b) found that “the threat of technologically advanced entry spurs innovation incentives in sectors close to the technology frontier, where successful innovation allows incumbents to survive the threat, but discourages innovation in laggard sectors, wh
43、ere the threat reduces incumbents expected rents from innovating.”Human capitalInnovation requires an education system able to produce a large enough body of scientists and applied researchers capable of moving the frontier of knowledge. The adoption of new technologies also requires a large body of
44、 highly qualified workers able to easily understand and operate the frontier technology. There must also be a major effort to make the frontier technology user-friendly. Human capital and skills formation are endogenously determined by educational choices and training.The role of human capital forma
45、tion for economic development has been emphasised by Lucas (1988).Financing of R&IIn a world of imperfect information, innovation financing faces a problem of asymmetric information between the innovator and the fund provider. Because of the non-rival nature of knowledge, the innovator has no intere
46、st in sharing with the fund provider some of the information the latter would need to justify the funding. Therefore, R&I is, as much as possible, financed through internal funds. In the absence of sufficient self-funding possibilities, external funding will have to be accessed. This external fundin
47、g can be private or public. Major sources of private funding include bank financing, capital markets and venture capital. Major sources of public funding include grants, subsidies, tax incentives and public venture capital. In their survey of empirical evidence, Hall and Lerner (2010) concluded “tha
48、t while small and new innovative firms experience high costs of capital the evidence for high costs of R&I capital for large firms is mixed. Nevertheless, large established firms do appear to prefer internal funds for financing such investments and they manage their cash flow to ensure this.”Evidenc
49、e on rates of return from R&ITo assess the effects of R&I on innovation, the concept of knowledge production functions is used. Innovation is assumed to be produced by means of an R&I technology using as inputs labour, capital (tangible and intangible, including research infrastructure, computers an
50、d software) and other intermediate inputs (including research materials such as protein structures). R&I labour is to a large extent comprised of scientists and technicians, ie highly skilled and specialised labour, whose research skills are acquired through specific R&I education (typically PhD deg
51、rees) and training. The productivity of firm-specific R&I technologies benefits from multiple knowledge spillovers, the assimilation of which may require some form of absorptive capacity.To obtain evidence on rates of return from R&I knowledge, production functions are estimated. Hall et al (2009),
52、summarising results from these studies, concluded that the rate of return in developed countries has been strongly positive, with the estimated private rate of return to R&I usually exceeding that of physical capital. Most studies obtain rates of return within the range of 10 percent to 30 percent.
53、They also report a large heterogeneity in rates of return for R&I across firms, technologies, sectors and countries.The returns to R&I may depend on the existence of complementarities between R&I and information and communication technologies (ICT), which allow productivity gains from doing research
54、 (Mohnen et al, 2018), or from in-house research combined with purchased technology (Cassiman and Veugelers, 2006), or from process and organisational innovation (Bresnahan et al, 2002).Another important issue is whether returns to R&I are constant. The original Romer (1990) model assumed that retur
55、ns to R&I are constant, which generates the undesirable property known as scale effect: since returns are constant, the growth rate of the economy positively depends on the economys size. Jones (1999), among others, argued that scale effects are counterfactual since large countries dont grow on aver
56、age faster than small countries. This controversy gave rise to the so-called semi-endogenous growth models, under the assumption of decreasing returns to R&I. Bloom et al (2017) claimed that ideas are getting harder to get, pointing out that research effort is increasing sharply, while research prod
57、uctivity is declining substantially in a wide range of sectors. By contrast, returns may also increase because of intertemporal R&I spillovers; the so-called standing on the giants shoulders argument (Scotchmer, 1991; Caballero and Jaffe, 1993).R&I policiesThe case for R&I policies: market failureTh
58、e fundamental justification for government support for research is the classic market failure argument: markets do not provide sufficient incentives for private investment in research owing to the non-appropriable, public good, intangible character of knowledge and its risky nature. In addition, pub
59、lic research is needed to meet specific needs of public interest, common goods that the market would not supply on its own, such as defence, public health or a clean environment. Once invented, the new knowledge created from R&I is non-rival and only partially non-excludable. Others may learn and us
60、e the knowledge, without necessarily paying for it. It is these spillovers, which include pure knowledge spillovers, as well as pecuniary spillovers, that lead to social rates of return above private rates of return and private investment levels below socially desirable levels. This divergence betwe
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 樓道維修合同范本
- 砭石療法與傳統(tǒng)中醫(yī)理論的關(guān)系及發(fā)展
- MEAI-hydrochloride-生命科學(xué)試劑-MCE
- 財(cái)務(wù)報(bào)銷合同范本
- 口罩代工合同范本
- 2-5-Dihydroxybenzoic-acid-sodium-Gentisic-acid-sodium-生命科學(xué)試劑-MCE
- 環(huán)保產(chǎn)業(yè)的人才培養(yǎng)與教育策略
- 科技創(chuàng)新與知識(shí)產(chǎn)權(quán)法的同步發(fā)展
- 科技教育下的電子商務(wù)培訓(xùn)新模式
- 電子競技文化的傳播與價(jià)值體現(xiàn)
- 運(yùn)維國企招聘筆試題庫
- 2024年興業(yè)數(shù)字金融服務(wù)上海股份有限公司招聘筆試參考題庫含答案解析
- 蘇教版二年級(jí)下冊(cè)科學(xué)全冊(cè)教案
- 挖掘機(jī)操作收藏手冊(cè)
- 教育家精神專題講座課件
- 了解綠化廢棄物的分類和處理方法
- 節(jié)后復(fù)工安全教育培訓(xùn)內(nèi)容【5篇】
- EPC項(xiàng)目投標(biāo)人承包人工程經(jīng)濟(jì)的合理性分析、評(píng)價(jià)
- 項(xiàng)目投標(biāo)BIM方案(投標(biāo)專用)
- 2024年中考數(shù)學(xué)專題訓(xùn)練 專題10 截長補(bǔ)短模型綜合應(yīng)用(知識(shí)解讀)
- 專利分析評(píng)議報(bào)告
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論