版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystemInternationalFinanceDiscussionPapers
ISSN1073-2500(Print)ISSN2767-4509(Online)
Number1397
October2024
HouseholdExcessSavingsandtheTransmissionofMonetaryPolicy
ThiagoR.T.Ferreira,NilsGornemann,JulioL.Ortiz
Pleasecitethispaperas:
Ferreira,ThiagoR.T.,NilsGornemann,JulioL.Ortiz(2024).“HouseholdEx-cessSavingsandtheTransmissionofMonetaryPolicy,”InternationalFinanceDiscus-sionPapers1397.Washington:BoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystem,
/10.17016/IFDP.2024.1397
.
NOTE:InternationalFinanceDiscussionPapers(IFDPs)arepreliminarymaterialscirculatedtostimu-latediscussionandcriticalcomment.TheanalysisandconclusionssetfortharethoseoftheauthorsanddonotindicateconcurrencebyothermembersoftheresearchstafortheBoardofGovernors.ReferencesinpublicationstotheInternationalFinanceDiscussionPapersSeries(otherthanacknowledgement)shouldbeclearedwiththeauthor(s)toprotectthetentativecharacterofthesepapers.RecentIFDPsareavailableontheWebat/pubs/ifdp/.ThispapercanbedownloadedwithoutchargefromtheSocialScienceResearchNetworkelectroniclibraryat.
HouseholdExcessSavingsandthe
TransmissionofMonetaryPolicy*
ThiagoR.T.FerreiratNilsGornemann?JulioL.Ortiz§
October8,2024
Abstract
HouseholdsavingsroseabovetrendinmanydevelopedcountriesaftertheonsetofCOVID-19.Givenitslinktoaggregateconsumption,thepresenceofthese“ex-cesssavings”hasraisedquestionsabouttheirimplicationsforthetransmissionofmonetarypolicy.Usingapanelofeuro-areaeconomiesandhigh-frequencymone-tarypolicyshocks,wedocumentthathouseholdexcesssavingsdampentheeffectsofmonetarypolicyoneconomicactivityandinflation,especiallyduringthepandemicperiod.Torationalizeourempiricalfindings,webuildaNewKeynesianmodelinwhichhouseholdsusesavingstoself-insureagainstcounter-cyclicalunemploymentandconsumptionrisk.
KeyWords:MonetaryPolicy,ExcessSavings,PrecautionarySavings,ConsumptionRisk,Unemployment
JELClassification:E12,E21,E24,E31,E52.
*WearegratefultoMitchLottforoutstandingresearchassistance.WealsothankMatteoIacoviello,PhillipJefferson,StevenOngena,ChristopherWaller,andpresentationattendeesattheFederalReserveBoardandthe2024IJCBconferencefortheircommentsandsuggestions.TheviewsexpressedinthispaperaresolelythoseoftheauthorsandshouldnotbeinterpretedasreflectingtheviewsoftheBoardofGovernorsoftheFederalReserveSystemorofanyotherpersonassociatedwiththeFederalReserve
Sys.eralReserveBoard,InternationalFinanceDivision;Washington,DC,20551,USA;Emailaddress:
thiago.r.teixeiraferreira@.
?FederalReserveBoard,InternationalFinanceDivision;Washington,DC,20551,USA;Emailaddress:nils.m.gornemann@.
§FederalReserveBoard,InternationalFinanceDivision;Washington,DC,20551,USA;Emailaddress:julio.l.ortiz@.
1
1Introduction
DuringtheCOVID-19pandemic,householdsaroundtheworldaccumulatedlargestocksofsavingsthroughacombinationofprecautionarymotives,aninabilitytospendtheirfundsamidwidespreadlockdowns,andincreasedfiscalsupporttotheirincomes.Soonafter,themainconcernofpolicymakersquicklyswitchedfromalleviatingthelackofhouseholdincometofightingdecades-highinflation.Still,householdsmaintainedrobuststocksof“excesssavings”(i.e.,savingsinexcessoftrend),andpolicymakersbegantoquestiontheirpossibleeffectsonthetransmissionofmonetarypolicy.
1
Inthispaper,weevaluatetheeffectsofexcesssavingsonmonetarypolicytransmission,bothempiricallyandtheoretically.Wedocumentthatexcesssavingsineuro-areaeconomiesrosetohistoricallyhighlevelsduringthepandemicperiod.Then,usinghigh-frequencymonetarypolicyshocks,weestimatestate-dependenteffectsofmonetarypolicyusinglocalprojections(
Jord`a,
2005
),andwefindthatmonetarypolicytransmissiontobothinflationandeconomicactivityisdampenedinperiodsofhighexcesssavings.Finally,werationalizehowexcesssavingsaffectthetransmissionofmonetarypolicyusingaNewKeynesianmodelinwhichhouseholdsfaceidiosyncratic,countercyclicalunemploymentandconsumptionriskagainstwhichtheycanonlyself-insurethroughsavings.
Webeginbymeasuringthestockofexcesssavingsandmonetarypolicyshocksforeuro-areaeconomies.Inadditiontotheeuro-areaaggregate,ourempiricalanalysisfocusesonthefourlargesteuro-areacountries:Germany,Italy,France,andSpain.Following
deSoyreset
al.
(2023),wedefinehouseholdexcesssavingsastheamountofsavingsarisingfromabove
-trendhouseholdsavingsrates.Toestimatecountry-leveltrendsavingsrates,weemploythe
Hamilton
(2018)filter
.Ourmeasureofexcesssavingsexhibitsvariationacrosstimeandcountries,withthepandemicperiodshowinghistoricallyhighlevels.Tomeasurethemonetarypolicyshocks,weapplythehigh-frequencyapproachof
Buetal.
(
2021
)totheeuroarea,whichaccountsforthemixofpoliciesfromtheEuropeanCentralBank(ECB)focusedonbothpolicyratesandassetpurchases.
Aftermeasuringtheseobjects,weusethemtoestimatetheeffectsofmonetarypolicyonrealandnominaloutcomes.Wefocusontwovariablesofinterest:theunemploymentrateandconsumerpriceinflation.Weestimatetheeffectsofmonetarypolicyontheseoutcomes
ofinterestvialocalprojections.Ourestimatesrevealthattheeffectofacontractionary
1Forinstance,seethe
speech
byChristineLagarde,PresidentoftheEuropeanCentralBank,at“TheECBandItsWatchersXXIII”conference.
2
monetarypolicyshockonrealandnominaloutcomesofinterestisattenuatedwhenstocksofexcesssavingsarelarger.Wefindthatourresultsarerobustto(i)differentmeasuresofeconomicactivity,(ii)controllingforthebalancesheetstrengthofthebankingsystem,and(iii)time-specificchangesaroundtheCOVIDperiod.
Ourempiricalresultscanbesummarizedasfollows.Wefindthatacontractionarymonetarypolicyshockscaledtogeneratea50basispointincreaseinthetwo-yearGermangovernmentyieldraisestheunemploymentratebyabout0.30percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsareclosetozero,butonlybyabout0.15percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsarefixedtotheir2023Q1levels.Additionally,weshowthattwelve-monthheadlineinflationdeclinesbynearly0.40percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsareclosetozero,butonlybyabout0.30percentagepointwhenexcesssavingsareconsistentwiththeirobserved2023Q1levels.Wechoosetoevaluatetheefficacyofmonetarypolicyin2023Q1becauseeuro-areaheadlineinflationpeakedaroundthistime,therebyconstitutingamomentatwhichpolicymakerspaidheightenedattentiontotheeffectivenessofmonetarypolicygoingforward.
Motivatedbyourempiricalfindings,webuildasimpleNewKeynesianmodelwithunemploymentandimperfectinsuranceagainstindividualunemploymentrisk.RelativetothestandardrepresentativeagentNewKeynesiansetting,savingsinourmodelarevaluedbecausetheyallowworkerstoself-insureagainsttheconsumptionriskofbeingunemployed.Unemploymentriskrisesduringcontractions,inducingworkerstocutbackconsumptionfurtheratthestartofadownturntosavemore.Thisresponseamplifiesthedirectimpactofanycontractionaryshock.Highersavingsattheonsetofthedownturnreducethiscon-sumptionresponseandthereforeleadtolessamplification.Asaresult,consistentwithourempiricalfindings,acalibratedversionofourmodelgeneratesdampenedrealandnominalresponsestomonetarypolicyshocksinahigh-savingseconomyrelativetothebaselineeconomy.Intotal,ourempiricalandquantitativeresultspointtoaneconomicallymean-ingfulnonlinearityinthepotencyofmonetarypolicybasedonthelevelofstocksofexcesssavings.
Ourpaperrelatestotherecentliteraturemeasuringexcesssavingsandstudyingtheiraggregateimplications.Ourmethodformeasuringexcesssavingsfollows
deSoyresetal.
(2023)
.Alternativeapproachestomeasuringexcesssavingsinclude
Aladangadyetal.
(2022)
and
AbdelrahmanandOliveira
(2023)
.Wetakeatime-varyingfilteringapproachbecauseitbestsuitsourpurposeofestimatingtheeffectsofmonetarypolicyshocksinapanelofeuro-areaeconomieswitharichtimedimension.Additionally,thereareotherrecent
3
studiesevaluatingtheeffectsofexcesssavingsaccumulatedduringCOVID-19.
Auclert
etal.
(2023)analyzestheprocessbywhichhouseholdexcesssavingsaffectthelevelof
aggregatedemand,andhowthisprocessvariesbasedonthedistributionofexcesssavings.
Aggarwaletal.
(2023)studydebt-financedfiscaltransfersinamodeloftheworldeconomy
thatreproduceslargefiscaldeficits,largeincreasesinprivatesavings,andpersistentcurrentaccountdeficits.Wecontributetothisliteraturebyempiricallyandquantitativelylinkingaggregateexcesssavingstomonetarypolicyeffectivenessinthecontextoftheeuroarea.
Ourpaperalsorelatestotheliteratureonthehowmonetarypolicytransmitstohouseholds.Recentcontributions,suchasthosemadeby
Cloyneetal.
(2020),findthat
mortgagorsaremoresensitivetomonetarypolicythanoutrightownersbecausethefor-merhavelittleliquidwealth.Inaddition,
HardingandKlein
(2022)and
Alpandaetal.
(2021)findempiricallythatmonetarypolicyismoreeffectiveinaffectingthemacroecon
-omywhenhouseholddebtisrisingorhigh
.2
Onthemodelingsideourpaperrelatestohouseholdmodelsofprecautionarysavingsdemandinthepresenceofcountercyclicalid-iosyncraticrisk,suchas
AcharyaandDogra
(2020),
Bilbiie
(2018),
Challeetal.
(2017),
Cho
(2023),
DenHaanetal.
(2018),
Gornemannetal.
(
2016
),and
RavnandSterk
(
2017
).Theempiricalstatedependencewedocumentcanbeviewedassupportiveofthemechanismsinthesepapers.Ourpaperissimilartothem,thoughitstudiesstatedependenthouseholdresponsivenesstomonetarypolicyacrossmajoreuro-areacountriesandinthecontextofexcesssavingsratherthanhouseholddebtornetworth.Ourmeasureofexcesssavings,particularlyaroundCOVID-19,likelyreflectsaninfluxofliquidsavingsthatallowedmanyEuropeanhouseholdstoremainclearofborrowingconstraintsduringtherecenttighteningcycle.
Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section
2
discussesthedatausedforourempiricalanalysis–particularlyourmeasuresofexcesssavingsandeuro-areamonetarypolicyshocks.Section
3
reportsourempiricalresults,whichshowthattheeffectsofmon-etarypolicyaredampenedwhenstocksofhouseholdexcesssavingsarehigh.Section
4
explorestheeconomicmechanismthroughwhichexcesssavingsaffectthetransmissionofmonetarypolicyinasimpleNewKeynesianmodelandpresentssimulationsrationalizingourempiricalresults.Section
5
concludes.
2
HardingandKlein
(2022)provideanalternativemechanismtorationalizeourfindings
.Intheirmodel,highersavingswouldrelaxacollateralconstraint,leadingtoadampeningofcontractionaryshockswhenconstrainedagentscutbackonconsumption.Weviewourmechanismascomplementarytotheirs.
4
2DataDescription
Inthissection,wedescribehowwemeasurethestocksofexcesssavingsandmonetarypolicyshocksusedforourempiricalresults.Appendix
A
providesfurtherdetailsonthedatausedinouranalysis.
2.1ExcessSavingsintheEuroArea
Figure1
StockofExcessSavingsintheEuroArea
Note:Figure
1
showstheseriesofstocksofexcesssavingsfortheeuro-areaaggregate(red),France(pink),Germany(blue),Italy(yellow),andSpain(green).
Wefollow
deSoyresetal.
(2023)bydefiningthestockofexcesssavingsastheamount
ofassets,asapercentofGDP,arisingfromabove-trendsavingsrates.First,foreachcountry,weextractatrendofthesavingsrateusingthe
Hamilton
(
2018
)filter
.3
Wethenusethedetrendedsavingsratetocalculatetheflowofexcesssavingsforcountryiinquartert,ineuros,asfollows:
Flowofexcesssavingsit=(DetrendedSavingsRateit)×(DisposableIncomeit).(1)
Toconstructthemeasureofthestockofexcesssavings,wecalculatethecumulativesum3Following
Hamilton
(2018),wedetrendthesavingsratecountrybycountryviaaregressionofthe
savingsrateonlags8to11.Theresidualisthedetrendedsavingsrate.
5
oftheflowsdefinedinequation(
1
)andnormalizeitbynominalGDP:
Stockofexcesssavingsit=×100.(2)
Finally,wedemeantheseriesatthecountrylevelovertheentiresampleperiod,whichspansfrom1999Q1through2023Q2
.4
Byconstruction,thestockofexcesssavingsincreaseswhentheflowofexcesssavingsispositive,whilethestockofexcesssavingsdecreaseswhentheflowofexcesssavingsisnegative.
Thismeasureofaggregateexcesssavingshassomeadvantages.First,itsconstruc-tionrequiresonlyaggregatenominalhouseholdsavings,disposableincome,andnominalGDP,allofwhicharereadilyavailableforavarietyofeuro-areacountries.Second,ourmethodologyproducesafulltimeseriesofestimatedexcesssavings,allowingustoexploititsvariationovertimeinouranalysis.Finally,despiteusingnominalhouseholdsavingsasaninput,ourmeasuredoesnotrelyontheassumptionthatpricesremainattheirtrends.
Ourmeasureofthestockofexcesssavingsfortheeuroareaexhibitsconsiderablevariation,bothinthetimeseriesandacrosscountries.Figure
1
showsthatinthelead-uptothe2008–2009GlobalFinancialCrisis,differenteconomieshaddifferenttrajectories,withItalyincreasingitsexcesssavings,FranceandGermanymaintainingtheirexcesssavings,andSpainandtheeuro-areaaggregatedecreasingtheirsavings.Incontrast,from2012to2020,mostoftheseeconomiesrandowntheirexcesssavings,withtheexceptionofFrance.Finally,amidtheCOVID-19pandemic,alloftheseeconomiessawtheirstocksofexcesssavingssharplyincrease.
2.2Euro-AreaHigh-FrequencyMonetaryPolicyShocks
Weapplythemethodologyof
Buetal.
(2021)tocalculatehigh-frequencymonetarypolicy
shocksfortheeuroarea.Specifically,weusedailydatafromtheGermanTreasuryyieldcurveforthemonetarypolicymeetingsoftheECBfortheperiodbetweenJanuary1999throughSeptember2022inourapplication.Figure
2
displaysthemonetarypolicyshocksthatarecalculatedusingthismethodology.Forourregressions,weaggregatetheseshocks
4Wedemeanthestockofexcesssavingswithincountrytoensurethatourempiricalresults,whichwedescribeinSection
3
,arenotdrivenbypermanentheterogeneityinexcesssavingsstemmingfrominitialconditionswhenaccumulatingthesavingsflowsovertime.
6
Figure2
MonetaryPolicyShocksfromtheEuropeanCentralBank
.2
.1
0
-.1
-.2
MonetaryPolicyShocksinPercentagePoints
20002005201020152020
Note:Figure
2
showsthetimeseriesofmonetarypolicyshockscalculatedusingGermanTreasuryyieldcurveforthemonetarypolicymeetingsoftheEuropeanCentralBankfortheperiodbetweenJanuary1999toSeptember2022.
bysummingthemtoamonthlyfrequency.
5
Ourchosenapproachtomeasuringmonetarypolicyshockscombinesthreeimportantfeaturesthataddressissuesextensivelydiscussedintheliterature.First,theshocksbridgeperiodsofconventionalandunconventionalmonetarypolicybyusinginterestratemove-mentsfromtheentireTreasuryyieldcurve.Second,
Buetal.
(
2021
)provideevidencethatthismethodologyremovesthecentralbankinformationeffectfortheUnitedStates:mon-etarypolicyannouncementsmayrevealinformationaboutthestateofthemacroeconomy,insteadofrepresentingonlygenuinemonetarypolicysurprises.Third,
Buetal.
(
2021
)documentthattheirU.S.monetarypolicyshocksarenotpredictedbyavailableinforma-tionontheeconomy,suchasBlueChipforecasts,newsreleases,andconsumersentiment
.6
Followingthesameapproach,inAppendix
B.1
weprovideevidencethatoureuroareamonetarypolicyshocksarenotpredictedbyinformationavailableinrealtime.
5WhenanalyzingtheconsumptionresponsetomonetarypolicyinAppendix
B.2
,weaggregatethemonetarypolicyshockstoaquarterlyfrequency.
6Formorediscussionoftheseissues,see
Miranda-Agrippino
(2016)and
BauerandSwanson
(2020)
.
7
3EmpiricalResults
Inthissection,weuseourmeasuresofexcesssavingsandeuro-areamonetarypolicyshockstodocumentthatexcesssavingsdampenthetransmissionofmonetarypolicytobotheconomicactivityandinflation.
3.1RegressionSpecifications
OursamplerunsfromJanuary1999throughSeptember2022andcoversfiveeconomies:theeuro-areaaggregate,Germany,France,Italy,andSpain.Werepresentaneconomywith
iandagivenmonthwitht.Theeuro-areamonetarypolicyshockisdenotedbyεand
isscaledsuchthattheshockgeneratesa50basispointincreaseinthetwo-yearGermangovernmentbondyield.Forallregressions,wealsospecifyasetofcountry-specificandeuro-area-specificcontrolsdenotedbyZit.Thecountry-specificcontrolsare12lagsofinflationrates,unemploymentrates,industrialproduction,GDPgrowth,andaninteractionofGDPgrowthwiththemonetarypolicyshocktoaccountforstate-dependenteffectsofmonetarypolicyoneconomicactivity(
TenreyroandThwaites,
2016)
.7
Theeuro-areacontrolsinclude12lagsofinflation,theunemploymentrate,andthespreadbetweenthefive-yearBBB-ratedbondyieldandthefive-yearGermangovernmentbondyield.
Weestimatethetransmissionofmonetarypolicytomeasuresofeconomicactivityandinflationunconditionallyandconditionalontheexantestockofexcesssavings.Specifically,weestimatethefollowinglocalprojections(
Jord`a,
2005
)atamonthlyfrequencyforaseriesofhorizonsh:
Yit+h?Yit?1=β+βε+β(ExcessSavingsStockit?1)×ε+γhZit?1+eit+h,(3)
whereYitisthemeasureofeconomicactivityandinflation.
Whilewefocusontheunemploymentrateasameasureofeconomicactivity,Appendix
B
documentsthatourresultsarerobusttousingbothaggregateconsumptionandindus-trialproductioninstead.Inaddition,wealsoshowthatourresultsarerobusttocontrollingfortheCOVIDperiodaswellasbankbalancesheetstrength,respectively.
7WeconvertGDPfromaquarterlyfrequencytoamonthlyfrequencybyassigningthevalueofrealizedGDPinagivenquartertoeverymonthofthatquarter.
8
Figure3
EffectofaContractionaryMonetaryPolicyShockonEuro-AreaUnemploymentRate
(a)AverageEffect(b)DampeningEffect
Note:Figure
3
depictstheresponseoftheunemploymentratetoamonetarypolicyshocknormalizedto
increase2-yearratesby50basispoints.Panel
3a
plotstheunconditionaleffect,β,fromlocalprojections
(3),whilePanel
3b
plotstheeffectconditionalonthelevelofexcesssavings,β.Theshadedareareflects
the68percentand90percentconfidenceintervalsusingstandarderrorsfrom
DriscollandKraay
(1998)
.
3.2ExcessSavingsDampenMonetaryPolicyEffectsonActivity
Usingtheunemploymentrateasameasureofeconomicactivity,wefindthateuro-areamonetarypolicyshocksincreasetheunemploymentratebutlesssowhenexcesssavingsarehigh.Figure
3a
plotstheunconditionaleffectsofmonetarypolicyshocks,withtheunemploymentraterisingovertime,reachingitspeakeffectafter15to20months,and
increasingby30basispoints.Figure
3b
plotstheestimateofβ,whichcapturesthenon-
linearityinmonetarytransmissionwithrespecttoexcesssavings.Moreprecisely,whenthestockofexcesssavingsofaeuro-areaeconomyincreasesbyonepercentagepointofGDPrelativetothehistoricalaverage,wefindthattheeffectofthemonetarypolicyshockontheunemploymentrateisdampenedbyroughlyone-half.Overall,ourestimatedeffectsofmonetarypolicyshocksoneconomicactivityarecomparableinmagnitudetothosefromotherpapers(e.g.,
BadingerandSchiman,
2023)
.
9
Figure4
EffectofaContractionaryMonetaryPolicyShockonEuro-AreaInflation
(a)AverageEffect(b)DampeningEffect
Note:Figure
4
plotstheresponseofinflationtoamonetarypolicyshocknormalizedtoincrease2-year
ratesby50basispoints.Panel
4a
plotstheunconditionaleffect,β,fromlocalprojections(
3
),whilePanel
4b
plotstheeffectconditionalonthelevelofexcesssavings,β.Theshadedareareflectsthe68percent
and90percentconfidenceintervalsusingstandarderrorsfrom
DriscollandKraay
(1998)
.
3.3ExcessSavingsDampenMonetaryPolicyEffectsonInflation
Inadditiontodampeningtheresponseofrealoutcomes,wefindevidencethatexcesssavingsalsodampentheresponseofprices.Weestimateequation(
3
)fortwelve-monthheadlineinflationandplottheresultsinFigure
4.
Theunconditionaleffect(Figure
4a
)showsthatinflationdeclinesby40basispointsinresponsetoacontractionarymonetarypolicyshock.Whenthestockofexcesssavingsofaeuro-areaeconomyisonepercentagepointofGDPrelativetoitshistoricalaverage(Figure
4b
),thedeclineininflationisdampenedbyaround10basispoints.Ourresultsareconsistentwiththeliteraturedocumentingthatusingahigh-frequencymeasurementofshockshelpstoshowthatinflationdecreasesaftercontractionarymonetarypolicyshocks(e.g.,
Ramey,
2016,
Jaroci′nskiandKaradi,
2020)
.
3.4MonetaryPolicyTransmissionPost-Pandemic
WenextquantifytheeffectoftheriseinexcesssavingsonthetransmissionofmonetarypolicyduringtheCOVID-19recovery.With12-monthheadlineinflationintheeuro-areaaggregatehavingpeakedin2022Q4andexcesssavingsstillremainingelevatedinthesame
10
Figure5
EffectofaContractionaryMonetaryPolicyShockin2023Q1
(a)Unemploymentrate(b)Inflation
Note:Figure
5
plotstheresponseoftheunemploymentrateandinflationtoamonetarypolicyshocknormalizedtoincrease2-yearratesby50basispoints.Panels
5a
and
5b
plotthetotalmonetarypolicy
effectundertwoscenarios:(i)whenexcesssavingsareequaltozero(i.e.,βfromlocalprojections(
3
))
and(ii)whenexcesssavingsaresetequaltotheir2023Q1levelbasedonanaverageofthecountriesinoursample.
period,weuseourestimatestoquantifytheeffectivenessofmonetarypolicyfromtheperspectiveofapolicymakerin2023Q1assheorhestartstoevaluatehowtightpolicywouldneedtobegoingforward.
Figure
5
showsthatexcesssavingsdampenedtheeffectsofmonetarypolicyduringtherecoveryfromthepandemic.Asabaseline,thebluelinesdepicttheaverageresponseoftheunemploymentandinflationratestoamonetarypolicyshockundertheassumptionthatexcesssavingsareattheirhistoricalaverages(thesameasinFigures
3a
and
4a,
respectively).Thesolidblacklinesreflecttheresponseoftheunemploymentandinflationratestoamonetarypolicyshockundertheassumptionthatexcesssavingsareattheir2023Q1levels.Comparingthetwosetsofresponses,weestimatepeak-dampeningeffectsofaboutone-fourthtoone-halfontheefficacyofmonetarypolicyforboththeunemploymentandinflationrates.
11
4ExcessSavingsinaSimpleNewKeynesianModel
Inthissection,webuildamodelthatprovidesaninterpretationofourempiricalresults:higherexcesssavingsflattentheIScurve.OurmodelisasimpleNewKeynesianmodelwithequilibriumunemploymentduetomatchingfrictionsinthelabormarket.Workersfaceidiosyncratic,countercyclicalunemploymentriskagainstwhichtheycanonlybepartiallyinsuredbysavingwhileemployed.Whenunemploymentriskrises,householdswanttocutconsumptiontodaytosavemore,whichthenamplifiestheresponseoftheeconomytotheinitialshock.However,highersavingsdampenthisamplificationbyallowingforbetterrisksharing.Ourexactset-upisasimplifiedversionofthemodelin
Challeetal.
(
2017
)andissimilarto,forexample,
RavnandSterk
(
2017
)and
HeathcoteandPerri
(
2018
).Thesameforcescanalsobefoundinlessstylizedmodelsofprecautionarysavingsoverthebusinesscyclelike
Gornemannetal.
(2016),
DenHaanetal.
(
2018
),and
Cho
(
2023
).
4.1Timeline
Theeconomyispopulatedbyaunitmassofidenticalfamilies.Eachfamilyitselfconsistsofaunitmassofworkers.Atthebeginningoftheperiod,thefamilyredistributesbondsbetweenitsmemberswhowereemployedlastperiod.Unemployedmembersofthefamilyalsomightholdsomebondsordebt,dependingontheirhistory.Importantly,theyarenotabletoshareinthewealthofthefamilyuntiltheyfindajob
.8
Aftertheredistributionofbondstookplace,aggregateshocksrealizeandfirmsannouncehowmanyworkerstheyplantohire.Employedworkersproduceforthefirmstheyworkforandarepaid.Unemployedworkersreceiveunemploymentbenefits.Bothgroupsthendecidehowtosplittheirincomebetweenconsumptionandsavings.Attheendoftheperiodallemployedmembersofafamilymeetandpoolresources,whicharethenre-shuffledbetweenthesefamilymembersforthenextperiod.
8Theassumptionofarepresentativefamilythatcanshareitsresourceswithinasubsetofworkersisclearlyunrealistic.Itismeanttocaptureaworldinwhichworkersself-insurethroughsavingagainstunemploymentrisk.Theassumptionthattheemployedworkersareabletopoolresources,however,stronglysimplifiestheanalysis.Thissimplificationarisesbecauseaworker’sassetpositiononlydependson
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 2025年度智慧城市門(mén)面店鋪轉(zhuǎn)讓及城市運(yùn)營(yíng)服務(wù)合同4篇
- 2025年度寵物醫(yī)院獸醫(yī)醫(yī)療廢物處理及環(huán)保合同4篇
- 二零二五年度美團(tuán)團(tuán)購(gòu)業(yè)務(wù)合同范本規(guī)范3篇
- 二零二四事業(yè)單位聘用合同簽訂風(fēng)險(xiǎn)控制與案例分析3篇
- 2025年度個(gè)人與企業(yè)間設(shè)備更新改造借款合同3篇
- 企業(yè)融資租賃合同協(xié)議書(shū)
- 2025年成都市二手房買(mǎi)賣(mài)合同范本下載適用于不同戶型4篇
- 室外廣告位出租合同
- 2025年度存量房居間買(mǎi)賣(mài)合同環(huán)保裝修指導(dǎo)細(xì)則2篇
- 二零二五年度農(nóng)藥生產(chǎn)許可證延續(xù)與更新服務(wù)合同4篇
- 消防產(chǎn)品目錄(2025年修訂本)
- 地方性分異規(guī)律下的植被演替課件高三地理二輪專題復(fù)習(xí)
- 光伏項(xiàng)目風(fēng)險(xiǎn)控制與安全方案
- 9.2提高防護(hù)能力教學(xué)設(shè)計(jì) 2024-2025學(xué)年統(tǒng)編版道德與法治七年級(jí)上冊(cè)
- 催收培訓(xùn)制度
- ISO 22003-1:2022《食品安全-第 1 部分:食品安全管理體系 審核與認(rèn)證機(jī)構(gòu)要求》中文版(機(jī)翻)
- 2024年廣東省高考地理真題(解析版)
- 2024高考物理廣東卷押題模擬含解析
- 人教版五年級(jí)上冊(cè)數(shù)學(xué)簡(jiǎn)便計(jì)算大全600題及答案
- GB/T 15945-1995電能質(zhì)量電力系統(tǒng)頻率允許偏差
- GB 32311-2015水電解制氫系統(tǒng)能效限定值及能效等級(jí)
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論