




免費(fèi)預(yù)覽已結(jié)束,剩余4頁(yè)可下載查看
下載本文檔
版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
文獻(xiàn)出自:Rabinovich E, Knemeyer A M, Mayer C M. Why do Internet commerce firms incorporate logistics service providers in their distribution channels?: The role of transaction costs and network strengthJ. Journal of Operations Management, 2007, 25(3): 661-681.Why do Internet commerce firms incorporate logistics service providers in their distribution channels: The role of transaction costs and network strengthAbstractThe Internet has redefined information-sharing boundaries in distribution channels and opened new avenues for managing logistics services. In the process, firms have started to incorporate new service providers in their commercial interactions with customers over the Internet. This paper studies conceptually and empirically why Internet commerce firms (ICFs) have established relationships with these providers. Focusing on logistics services in outbound distribution channels, we rely on transaction cost theory to reveal that low levels of asset specificity and uncertainty drive Internet commerce firms to establish these relationships. Moreover, we apply strategic network theory to show that Internet commerce firms seek these providers because they offer access to relationship networks that bundle many complementary logistics services. In addition, logistics service providers make these services available across new and existing relationships between the Internet commerce firms, their customers, and their vendors.1. IntroductionThe growth of electronic commerce has driven Internet commerce firms (ICFs) retailers and other organizations that market products over the Web to increasingly share market demand data with other firms so as to enrich the order fulfillment services they offer to customers (Frohlich and Westbrook, 2002). Along these efforts, ICFs have started seeking logistics service providers to tap into resources and skills that could improve their fulfillment capabilities (Dutta and Segev, 1999).These logistics service providers are not simply variants of transportation companies, and as such, they are not to be confused with what are known nowadays as third party logistics (3PL) firms. They offer logistics services, of course, but they could also enable ICFs to leverage other distribution parties logistical resources and skills in order to fulfill their customer orders more effectively. They may use their assets to take care of product returns, for instance, or work with established carriers on “l(fā)ast-mile” deliveries. Or their value may be primarily in managing order information shared among distribution partiese.g., centralizing inventory data, especially when products are being shipped directly from upstream echelons in the distribution channel. Logistics service providers such as Parcel Direct, for instance, participate in this kind of activity to ultimately assist ICFs in consolidating orders for drop-shipping to their customers.Past research has identified the relationships with these logistics service providers in offline settings and has positioned them within logistics triads (Larson and Gammelgaard, 2001) and extended-enterprise logistics systems (Stock et al., 2000). Yet, what is ground-breaking about these relationships for an ICF is that they are driven by their potential to (1) generate low transaction costs, (2) bundle complementary logistics services, and (3) expand the availability of those services across customers, vendors, and “l(fā)ast-mile” delivery companies, such as UPS (Amit and Zott, 2001).The goal of this study is to conceptualize and empirically assess how these drivers shape ICF managements decisions to develop mechanisms to form and manage dyadic exchanges between their firms and focal organizations offering logistics services in outbound distribution channels. Prior literature has used the term “governance” to define these mechanisms (Barney, 1999, p. 138) and has delineated governance decisions through which a firm can infuse order in exchanges with a focal provider where potential conflicts threaten to undo or upset opportunities to realize economic gains (Williamson, 1999, p. 1090). These decisions center on the extent to which firms rely on a particular governance mode for a service. Since our research context focuses on outbound distribution channels, we define such reliance as the proportion of Internet orders for which a governance mode is used for a service supporting the fulfillment of those orders. This definition is consistent with that used by John and Weitz (1988) for distribution in an offline setting.Our conceptualization and empirical assessment are unique because they recognize that governance in an exchange between an ICF and a focal logistics service provider is embedded within a networked structure that also comprises a broader collection of relational links among other distribution-channel members (Chen and Paulraj, 2004andJones et al., 1997). In this context, our research is primarily concerned with ICFs reliance on networked governance structures. These structures have been defined as economic forms of organization that are built on reciprocal exchange patterns, enabling firms (in this case, ICFs) to obtain resources and services through dyadic relationships with other organizations (i.e., focal logistics service providers), as well as through broader relational links where these relationships exist ( Powell, 1990andGulati, 1998).To fulfill the goal of this study, Section 2 positions our research in the strategic- and operations-management literatures. Also, it develops the theoretical foundation and hypotheses that articulate a decision-making framework for ICF reliance on networked governance structures for logistics services. Section 3 discusses methodological issues pertaining to the data collection and the operationalization of the constructs developed as part of the theoretical framework presented in Section 2. We analyze the empirical results in Section 4. Finally, we conclude in Section 5 with a presentation of findings, academic and practical contributions, and future research opportunities stemming from our study.2. Theoretical frameworkBecause networked governance structures are based on linkages among interdependent firms (Powell, 1990), they constitute an alternate form of exchange (Spulber, 1996) that expands two traditional forms: perfectly competitive markets and vertically integrated hierarchies (Williamson, 1975). Theoretically, decisions to adopt such exchanges rest on costs potentially incurred by ICFs when they establish market-based linkages with focal providers to manage i.e., plan, organize, operate, and control logistics services (Madhok, 2002). However, these decisions are also linked to scale, skills, and resources that ICFs may obtain in broader networks of services and entities accessible through their relationships with focal providers (Doz and Hamel, 1998andGulati, 1998).Consequently, our assessment of these decisions integrates two distinct theoretical perspectives: transaction cost theory and strategic network theory. Transaction cost theory helps us understand how efforts and risks in establishing links with focal logistics service providers are related to expenditures that impact ICFs reliance on these specialists. Through strategic network theory, and in accordance with its definition, we can establish how the access offered by focal logistics service providers to networked governance structures shapes ICFs relationships with the providers (Granovetter, 1973).This integration adds to extant literature that has independently relied on transaction cost and strategic network theories to conceptualize similar phenomena at a strategic level (e.g., Eccles, 1981, Katz and Shapiro, 1985, Granovetter, 1992andJones et al., 1997). The integration builds on work by Amit and Zott (2001), who used exploratory case studies to apply these theories to an Internet setting and concluded that neither of these theories can fully explain by itself value creation across different governance structures present in Internet business models. Therefore, Amit and Zott (2001) posit that transaction cost and strategic network theories complement each other in explaining the emergence of governance structures in Internet settings.Individually, transaction cost theory focuses on an exchange between two parties (e.g., an ICF and a focal logistics service provider) as a discrete event that is valuable by itself, as it reflects the choice of the most efficient governance form and hence contributes to lower the exchange costs incurred by one of the parties, i.e., the ICF. Strategic network theory complements transaction cost theory because it considers the individual dyadic exchange collectively with other relational links that may accompany that exchange (Amit and Zott, 2001). This does not mean, however, that strategic network theory would become the dominant research view, thus rendering transaction cost theory irrelevant. By articulating a framework necessary to define the choice regarding the most efficient governance form in the exchange between an ICF and its focal provider, transaction cost theory would actually pave the way for strategic network theory to define whether resources and services available through other links surrounding the ICFprovider exchange would confirm or modify that choice (Amit and Zott, 2001).Within operations management, our assessment of these theories answers calls by researchers to offer a better understanding of (1) decision-making mechanisms behind the development of relationships between firms (Mabert and Venkataramanan, 1998) and (2) managerial decisions concerning logistics operations in inter-firm relationships (Grover and Malhotra, 2003). As a result, our research contributes to the operations-management literature because it offers a more detailed understanding as to why firms, in this case ICFs, utilize alternative structures to incorporate solution specialists, in general, and logistics service providers, in particular, into their distribution channels.Moreover, in studying decisions about the management of inter-firm exchanges, our research conceptualization follows that introduced by Choi et al. (2001) and Choi and Hong (2002), who advocated that operational decisions around inter-organizational exchanges be positioned within larger networks of firms. However, by focusing on logistics services necessary to carry out the fulfillment of customer orders, we extend those conceptualizations from a manufacturing context to a service setting. This allows us to study not only cost considerations, but also value-adding parameters in decisions to incorporate networked governance structures to connect with other distribution-channel members.Our assessment of decisions by ICF management to form networked governance structures also contributes to literature in service operations management. With the advent of Internet commerce, experts predicted that greater opportunities for information interaction between ICFs and other distribution-channel members would lead to greater efficiency in the performance of distribution-channel services (Benjamin and Wigand, 1995). In theory, this efficiency would inevitably compel ICFs to lower their prices to compete with other organizations. Otherwise, ICFs would likely succumb to price-aggressive competitors who would be able to offer these same services to customers at relatively lower costs (Giaglis et al., 2002).In fact, Dell Computers and other ICFs have succeeded at increasing the efficiency of their distribution channels by offering wide product variety at low prices. However, evidence suggests that other ICFs have chosen not to rely exclusively on low prices to compete and instead have obtained price premiums by offering services with the support of providers in areas such as logistics (Maltz et al., 2004). After all, through logistics services, providers can add value to Internet transactions by allowing customers to obtain exact product specifications that match their needs (Boyer et al., 2002). Moreover, Internet customer satisfaction (Thirumalai and Sinha, 2005), loyalty (Heim and Sinha, 2001), and, thus, willingness to ultimately pay price premiums (Rabinovich and Bailey, 2004) are likely to be related to the availability of those services.中文翻譯為什么網(wǎng)絡(luò)電子商務(wù)公司將其分銷渠道中的物流服務(wù)歸于交易成本的作用和網(wǎng)絡(luò)的力量摘要:互聯(lián)網(wǎng)重新定義了信息共享邊界的分銷渠道和物流管理服務(wù)開(kāi)辟了新的途徑。在這個(gè)過(guò)程中,公司已經(jīng)開(kāi)始把新的服務(wù)提供商在他們的商業(yè)在互聯(lián)網(wǎng)上與客戶互動(dòng)。本文研究的概念上和經(jīng)驗(yàn)的互聯(lián)網(wǎng)電子商務(wù)公司(ICFS)與這些供應(yīng)商建立了合作關(guān)系。專注于物流服務(wù),在出站的分銷渠道,我們依靠交易成本理論表明,水平低的資產(chǎn)專用性和不確定性驅(qū)動(dòng)的互聯(lián)網(wǎng)電子商務(wù)公司要建立這些關(guān)系。此外,我們實(shí)施戰(zhàn)略網(wǎng)絡(luò)理論表明,互聯(lián)網(wǎng)電子商務(wù)公司提供許多互補(bǔ)的物流服務(wù)捆綁的關(guān)系網(wǎng)絡(luò),尋求供應(yīng)商,因?yàn)樗麄?。此外,物流服?wù)供應(yīng)商提供這些服務(wù)跨越新的和現(xiàn)有的互聯(lián)網(wǎng)電子商務(wù)公司,他們的客戶和他們的供應(yīng)商之間的關(guān)系。1.介紹電子商務(wù)的增長(zhǎng)推動(dòng)了互聯(lián)網(wǎng)電子商務(wù)公司(ICFS) - 零售商和其他機(jī)構(gòu)越來(lái)越多地分享市場(chǎng)的產(chǎn)品通過(guò)Web - 與其他公司的市場(chǎng)需求數(shù)據(jù),以豐富他們提供給客戶的訂單執(zhí)行服務(wù)(Frohlich和威斯布魯克,2002)。隨著這些努力,ICFS已經(jīng)開(kāi)始尋求物流服務(wù)供應(yīng)商進(jìn)軍資源和技能,可以提高他們的履行能力(Dutta和塞格夫,1999年)。這些物流服務(wù)供應(yīng)商不能簡(jiǎn)單地運(yùn)輸公司的變種,正因?yàn)槿绱?,他們現(xiàn)在被稱為第三方物流(3PL)公司是不被混淆。當(dāng)然,他們提供物流服務(wù),但他們還可以使ICFS利用其他分銷各方的后勤資源和技能,以更有效地履行他們的客戶訂單。產(chǎn)品的回報(bào)率,例如照顧,或與既定的“最后一英里”的交付運(yùn)營(yíng)商,他們可以利用自己的資產(chǎn)?;蛘咚麄兊膬r(jià)值可能主要在訂單信息共享之間的分布各方,例如管理,集中庫(kù)存數(shù)據(jù),特別是當(dāng)產(chǎn)品被運(yùn)往在分銷渠道直接從上游梯隊(duì)。物流服務(wù)供應(yīng)商,如包裹直接,例如,參加這樣的活動(dòng),最終協(xié)助ICFS在鞏固他們的客戶訂單下降,航運(yùn)。過(guò)去的研究已經(jīng)確定了脫機(jī)設(shè)置這些物流服務(wù)供應(yīng)商的關(guān)系,他們?cè)谖锪骱谏鐣?huì)(拉爾森和Gammelgaard,2001年)和擴(kuò)展企業(yè)的物流系統(tǒng)(Stock等人,2000)。然而,什么是這些關(guān)系的ICF是突破性的,他們都在為自己的潛力:(1)生成低交易成本,(2)捆綁互補(bǔ)性的物流服務(wù),及(3)擴(kuò)大客戶提供這些服務(wù)的整個(gè),供應(yīng)商和“最后一公里”的快遞公司,如UPS(Amit和Zott,2001年)。本研究的目的是概念化和實(shí)證評(píng)估這些驅(qū)動(dòng)程序的形狀I(lǐng)CF管理層的決定是如何建立機(jī)制,形成二元之間的交流和管理他們的公司提供物流服務(wù),在出站的分銷渠道和聯(lián)絡(luò)組織。之前的文獻(xiàn)中使用了“管理”一詞來(lái)定義這些機(jī)制(巴尼,1999年,第138頁(yè)),并劃定了管理決策的公司注入秩序的交流與重點(diǎn)供應(yīng)商,潛在的沖突威脅撤消或不高興的機(jī)會(huì)實(shí)現(xiàn)經(jīng)濟(jì)收益(威廉姆森,1999年,1090年)。這些決定公司在何種程度上依賴于一個(gè)特定的治理模式的服務(wù)中心。由于我們的研究?jī)?nèi)容集中在出站的分銷渠道,我們定義這種依賴的治理模式,用于支持履行這些訂單的服務(wù)網(wǎng)絡(luò)訂單的比例。這個(gè)定義是一致的分布由約翰和Weitz(1988)為在脫機(jī)設(shè)置。我們的概念化和實(shí)證評(píng)估是獨(dú)一無(wú)二的,因?yàn)樗麄冋J(rèn)識(shí)到,治理被嵌入到一個(gè)網(wǎng)絡(luò)結(jié)構(gòu),還包括其他分銷渠道成員關(guān)系之間的聯(lián)系,更廣泛的收集(陳和Paulraj在ICF和重點(diǎn)物流服務(wù)供應(yīng)商之間的交流, 2004年,Jones等人,1997)。在這種情況下,我們的研究主要關(guān)注的與ICFS依賴網(wǎng)絡(luò)的治理結(jié)構(gòu)。這些結(jié)構(gòu)都被定義為經(jīng)濟(jì)的組織形式,是建立在相互交換模式,使企業(yè)(在這種情況下,ICFS)獲得的資源和服務(wù),通過(guò)與其他組織(如重點(diǎn)物流服務(wù)供應(yīng)商)的二元關(guān)系,以及通過(guò)這些關(guān)系存在的更廣泛的關(guān)系鏈接(鮑威爾,1990年和古拉蒂,1998年)。為了完成這項(xiàng)研究的目標(biāo),我們的研究第2個(gè)位置的戰(zhàn)略和運(yùn)營(yíng)管理文獻(xiàn)。此外,它的發(fā)展的理論基礎(chǔ)和假設(shè),闡明一個(gè)決策網(wǎng)絡(luò)治理結(jié)構(gòu)的框架為ICF依賴于物流服務(wù)。第3節(jié)討論的方法問(wèn)題,有關(guān)的數(shù)據(jù)收集和運(yùn)作的第2節(jié)中提出的理論框架的一部分開(kāi)發(fā)的結(jié)構(gòu)。在第4節(jié),我們分析了實(shí)證結(jié)果。最后,我們的結(jié)論在第5節(jié)的調(diào)查結(jié)果,學(xué)術(shù)界和實(shí)際貢獻(xiàn)和未來(lái)的研究機(jī)會(huì),從我們的研究帶來(lái)演示。2.理論框架由于網(wǎng)絡(luò)的治理結(jié)構(gòu),根據(jù)之間的聯(lián)系,相互依存的企業(yè)(鮑威爾,1990年),它們構(gòu)成了另一種形式的交流(Spulber,1996年),擴(kuò)大兩個(gè)傳統(tǒng)的形式:完全競(jìng)爭(zhēng)市場(chǎng),垂直整合的層次結(jié)構(gòu)(威廉姆森,1975)。從理論上講,決定采用這樣的交流,其余的成本可能所產(chǎn)生的ICFS時(shí),建立以市場(chǎng)為基礎(chǔ)的聯(lián)系與聯(lián)絡(luò)供應(yīng)商管理 - 即計(jì)劃,組織,運(yùn)作和控制 - 物流服務(wù)(Madhok,2002年)的。然而,這些決定也與ICFS可能會(huì)獲得更廣泛的網(wǎng)絡(luò)服務(wù)和實(shí)體可以通過(guò)與重點(diǎn)供應(yīng)商的關(guān)系(打和Hamel,1998年和古拉蒂,1998年)的規(guī)模,技能和資源。因此,我們?cè)u(píng)估這些決策集成了兩個(gè)不
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 科技推動(dòng)醫(yī)療技術(shù)革新及產(chǎn)業(yè)發(fā)展
- (一模)臨沂市2025屆高三高考第一次模擬考試歷史試卷(含標(biāo)準(zhǔn)答案)
- 戰(zhàn)略思考能力的培養(yǎng)計(jì)劃
- 財(cái)務(wù)風(fēng)險(xiǎn)識(shí)別與評(píng)估的方法論
- 質(zhì)量文化的建設(shè)與傳播策略
- 跨國(guó)企業(yè)知識(shí)產(chǎn)權(quán)培訓(xùn)與教育體系構(gòu)建
- 金融科技公司財(cái)報(bào)特點(diǎn)與趨勢(shì)分析
- 超聲波在材料科學(xué)的研究應(yīng)用
- 超快速激脈沖技術(shù)在航空航天領(lǐng)域的應(yīng)用與展望
- 貴州國(guó)企招聘2024銅仁市扶貧開(kāi)發(fā)投資有限責(zé)任公司招聘11人筆試參考題庫(kù)附帶答案詳解
- 2023風(fēng)力發(fā)電機(jī)組延壽評(píng)估技術(shù)規(guī)范
- 鞋業(yè)-品質(zhì)培訓(xùn)
- 小學(xué)思政課《愛(ài)國(guó)主義教育》
- 瓜豆原理【模型專題】(含答案解析)
- 單價(jià)、數(shù)量、總價(jià)-教學(xué)課件【A3演示文稿設(shè)計(jì)與制作】
- 中小學(xué)生安全教育手冊(cè)全面版
- 變電站安裝工程安全風(fēng)險(xiǎn)分級(jí)管控清單
- DDI-能力解構(gòu)詞典
- 燃?xì)夤艿拦こ瘫O(jiān)理實(shí)施細(xì)則
- 安全經(jīng)驗(yàn)分享之行車安全經(jīng)驗(yàn)分享
- 忻州市忻府區(qū)康益種植園利用粉煤灰開(kāi)發(fā)造地項(xiàng)目?環(huán)評(píng)報(bào)告
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論