




版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請進(jìn)行舉報或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡介
Fed
Transparency
andPolicy
Expectation
Errors:A
TextAnalysis
ApproachNO.
1081NOVEMBER
2023EricFischer
|
Rebecca
McCaughrin
|
Saketh
Prazad
|MarkVandergonFedTransparency
andPolicyExpectationErrors:ATextAnalysisApproachEricFischer,RebeccaMcCaughrin,SakethPrazad,andMarkVandergonFederalReserveBank
ofNew
YorkStaffReports,no.1081November2023/10.59576/sr.1081AbstractThispaperseekstoestimatethe
extenttowhichmarket-impliedpolicyexpectationscouldbeimprovedwith
furtherinformationdisclosurefromtheFOMC.Using
textanalysismethodsbased
onlargelanguagemodels,we
show
thatif
FOMCmeeting
materialswithfive-yearlaggedreleasedates—likemeetingtranscriptsandTealbooks—wereaccessibleto
thepublicin
realtime,
marketpolicyexpectationscouldsubstantiallyimproveforecastingaccuracy.Most
of
thisimprovementoccursduringeasing
cycles.Forinstance,at
thesix-monthforecasting
horizon,the
marketcould
havepredictedasmuch
as125basispointsof
additionaleasingduringthe2001and2008recessions,equivalenttoa40-50percentreductioninmean
squarederror.Thispotentialforecastingimprovementappearstobe
relatedto
incompleteinformation
abouttheFed’sreactionfunction,particularlywithrespecttofinancialstabilityconcernsin2008.Incontrast,
havingenhancedaccessto
meeting
materialswouldnot
haveimprovedthe
market’spolicyrateforecasting
duringtighteningcycles.JELclassification:
E43,E52,E58,C80Keywords:interestrates,
monetarypolicy,centralbankandpolicy,sentimentanalysis_________________Fischer,
McCaughrin:MarketsGroup,FederalReserveBankof
NewYork(email:eric.fischer@,
mccaughrin@).Prazad:ResearchAnalyst,ResearchGroup,FederalReserveBank
ofNewYork(email:saketh.prazad@).Vandergon:TechnologyGroup,FederalReserveBank
ofNewYork(email:mark.vandergon@).TheauthorsthankMichaelBauer,RyanBush,RichardCrump,MatthewGentzkow,SeungLee,EricOffner,ChiaraScotti,Adam
Shapiro,DerekTang,andseminarparticipantsattheFederalReserveBank
ofNewYork,theFederalReserveBoard,
theFederalReserveBankofAtlantaQuantitativeSkills
Conference,
andtheWesternEconomicAssociationInternational
Conferenceforhelpfulcomments.
TheyalsothankFederalReserveBankofNewYorkMarketsGroupanalystsforassistance
with
sentenceannotationandThiernoDialloforexcellentresearchassistance.Thispaperpresentspreliminaryfindingsand
is
beingdistributedto
economistsand
otherinterestedreaderssolely
to
stimulatediscussionandelicitcomments.Theviews
expressedinthispaperare
thoseoftheauthor(s)anddonotnecessarilyreflectthepositionoftheFederalReserveBankofNewYorkortheFederalReserveSystem.Anyerrorsoromissionsaretheresponsibility
ofthe
author(s).Toview
the
authors’disclosurestatements,visit/research/staff_reports/sr1081.html.1
IntroductionOver
the
last
few
decades,
central
banks
have
made
substantial
changes
to
their
communica-tions
and
transparency
practices
in
an
e?ort
to
improve
market
expectations
of
future
monetarypolicy.
Clear
and
e?ective
communications
help
to
ensure
that
policy
shifts
are
properly
transmit-ted
to
?nancial
conditions
and
the
real
economy.
Recent
work
on
monetary
policy
expectations
hasdocumented
that
while
market
expectations
may
often
be
unbiased
predictors
of
the
future
policyrate,
there
can
be
substantial
ex-post
predictability
of
market
expectation
errors,
particularly
dur-ing
signi?cant
policy
easing
episodes
(Cieslak,
2018),
(Schmeling,
Schrimpf
and
Ste?ensen,
2022),(Bauer
and
Swanson,
2023).
These
expectation
errors
are
believed
to
be
ex-ante
unpredictable
anddriven
by
an
underestimation
of
the
central
bank’s
sensitivity
to
economic
downturns.
In
this
pa-per,
we
argue
that
Fed
transparency
plays
some
role
in
these
expectation
errors,
and
demonstratethat
a
portion
of
the
expectation
errors
are
predictable
ex-ante,
given
enhanced
access
to
informa-tion
from
monetary
policy
meetings.We
de?ne
transparency
in
terms
of
information
loss
between
the
public
and
the
Fed
with
respectto
expectations
of
future
monetary
policy.
In
a
procedural
sense,
central
banks
are
not
fully
trans-parent.
Monetary
policy
meeting
deliberations
are
con?dential.
Transcripts
and
related
brie?ngmaterials
are
only
released
to
the
public
with
a
signi?cant
lag.
To
be
sure,
central
banks
have
legit-imate
reasons
to
maintain
con?dentiality
or
institute
lags
in
providing
access
to
information.
Suchopacity,
which
we
de?ne
as
the
inverse
of
transparency,
may
be
deemed
necessary,
for
instance,to
maintain
independence
and
encourage
objective
and
vigorous
debate
among
policymakers.
Ifinternal
discussions
and
sta?
economic
forecasts
were
to
become
immediately
available
to
the
pub-lic,
market
participants
could
perceive
such
forecasts
as
a
commitment
to
certain
future
actions
bythe
central
bank,
which
could
in
turn
reduce
the
?exibility
of
the
central
bank
in
the
future.In
lieu
of
immediate
access
to
meeting
materials,
the
public
receives
a
wide
range
of
commu-nications
from
the
Fed,
including
statements,
meeting
minutes,
speeches,
interviews,
and
pressconferences.
If
these
communications
can
be
used
to
accurately
predict
the
Fed’s
future
policy
de-cisions,
despite
the
con?dentiality
of
meetings,
then
we
posit
that
there
is
no
information
loss.
Inthis
paper,
we
do
not
attempt
to
weigh
the
trade-o?s
of
increased
transparency
against
potentialimprovements
in
market
policy
forecasts.
Rather,
our
goal
is
to
highlight
potential
costs
of
opacitythat
have
been
previously
unacknowledged
by
the
literature.1We
measure
information
loss
by
comparing
actual
market
policy
expectations
with
our
pre-dictions
of
what
market
expectations
would
have
been
in
a
counterfactual
world
in
which
the
Fedreleases
meeting
transcripts
and
Tealbooks
immediately
instead
of
with
a
?ve
year
lag.1
Thesecounterfactual
predictions
are
generated
using
our
“FedSpeak
model”,
a
forecasting
model
thatpredicts
the
change
in
the
fed
funds
rate
h
months
after
meeting
t,
using
fed
funds
futures
fromthe
day
after
meeting
t,
con?dential
sentiment
and
topic
content
from
meeting
t,
and
con?dentialTealbook
forecasts
from
meeting
t.2
One
day
after
a
meeting,
the
futures
market
should
have
pricedin
all
relevant
information
released
before
the
meeting,
including
meeting
minutes,
speeches,
andmacroeconomic
data
releases.We
produce
time-varying
measures
of
sentiment
and
topic
content
of
meeting
transcripts
andTealbooks.
Topic
modeling
and
sentiment
analysis
are
standard
machine
learning
techniques
thatallow
for
a
detailed
quantitative
assessment
of
how
subjective
content
of
text
changes
over
time.We
measure
sentiment
and
topic
at
the
sentence-level.
A
sentence
can
have
a
sentiment
label
of“Positive”,
“Negative”,
or
“Neutral”.
The
same
sentence
can
also
have
a
topic
label
of
“EconomicGrowth”,
“In?ation”,
“Labor
Markets”,
“Financial
Stability”,
and
“Monetary
Policy”.
A
sentencemay
also
have
no
associated
topic
label.
The
text
analysis
is
conducted
using
supervised
machinelearning
methods
and
large
language
models,
which
we
train
using
a
dataset
of
sentences
fromFOMC
speeches,
statements,
minutes,
transcripts,
and
interviews.
The
topic
and
sentiment
la-bels
for
this
training
dataset
were
determined
by
analysts
from
the
Markets
Group
at
the
FederalReserve
Bank
of
New
York.
We
show
that
our
machine
learning-based
approaches
generate
im-provements
in
accuracy
on
a
held-out
test
set
relative
to
the
lexical
approaches
commonly
used
ineconomics.We
show
that
the
out-of-sample
predictions
of
the
FedSpeak
model
signi?cantly
outperformfed
funds
futures
at
three-,
six-,
and
nine-month
forecasting
horizons,
thus
indicating
opacity.
Theoutperformance
we
?nd
for
the
full
1996
to
2016
period
reveals
an
important
asymmetry
betweentightening
and
easing
cycles.
During
the
2001
and
2008
easing
cycles,
the
gap
between
fed
fundsfutures
and
the
FedSpeak
model’s
predictions
was
as
much
as
125
basis
points
at
the
six
month1Before
2010,
the
two
main
sta?
brie?ng
documents
were
the
Greenbook,
which
summarized
economic
develop-ments,
and
the
Bluebook,
which
summarized
monetary
policy
options.
In
2010,
the
two
documents
were
merged
intothe
Tealbook.
For
the
rest
of
this
paper,
when
we
refer
to
“Tealbook”,
we
refer
to
the
pre-2010
Greenbooks
and
thepost-2010
Tealbooks.
We
do
not
consider
Bluebooks.2In
this
counterfactual
world,
we
assume
that
the
Fed
does
not
adjust
the
contents
of
its
meetings
in
response
togreater
transparency.2horizon,
equivalent
to
a
40-50%
reduction
in
mean
squared
error.
We
?nd
no
such
outperformanceduring
tightening
cycles
and
during
the
zero
lower
bound.
These
results
imply
that
Fed
communi-cations
may
be
less
informative
during
easing
cycles,
to
the
extent
that
meeting
materials
containedpolicy-relevant
information
not
re?ected
in
market
pricing.One
potential
explanation
for
our
results
is
that
although
the
market
takes
into
account
com-munications
released
before
meeting
t,
a
large
portion
of
the
important
information
within
meetingtranscripts
is
released
to
the
public
in
the
speeches
and
minutes
released
after
meeting
t.
If
post-meeting
communications
are
highly
informative,
then
the
opacity
we
identify
in
our
main
resultsmay
be
temporary.
To
account
for
this
possibility,
we
implement
our
forecasting
exercise
with
amodi?ed
FedSpeak
model
that
pairs
market
expectations
one
day
after
meeting
t
with
meeting
ma-terials
from
meeting
t
?1
(rather
than
from
meeting
t).
If
post-meeting
communications
eliminateopacity,
then
information
from
meeting
t
?1
should
no
longer
be
important
since
Fed
communi-cations
released
between
meeting
t
?
1
and
meeting
t
would
have
been
priced
in
by
the
market.Instead,
we
?nd
the
modi?ed
FedSpeak
model
continues
to
outperform
the
market
during
easingcycles,
though
by
a
somewhat
lower
magnitude.
This
suggests
that
opacity
persists
many
weeksafter
a
meeting.Using
an
alternative
metric
of
transparency,
we
verify
the
implication
that
the
outperformanceof
the
FedSpeak
model
re?ects
less
informative
communications
during
easing
cycles.
To
do
this,we
test
whether
a
hypothetical
investor
could
have
used
meeting
minutes
in
real
time
to
predictthe
contents
of
con?dential
meeting
transcripts.
The
investor
estimates
the
historical
relationshipbetween
the
contents
of
meetings
minutes
and
the
contents
of
meeting
transcripts
and
then
ap-plies
that
historical
relationship
to
new
minutes
observations
in
order
to
generate
predictions
oftranscript
content.
We
compare
these
predictions
with
actual
transcript
content
in
order
to
assesstransparency.
We
continue
to
?nd
an
asymmetry
between
tightening
cycles
and
easing
cycles.
Inparticular,
predicted
transcript
sentiment
tends
to
be
more
positive
than
actual
transcript
sentimentduring
easing
cycles,
which
we
posit
may
explain
why
the
market
underestimated
future
rate
cuts.We
o?er
two
main
caveats
to
our
analysis.
First,
our
results
cannot
identify
whether
recentinnovations
in
Fed
communications,
like
the
Summary
of
Economic
Projections
(SEP)
and
pressconferences,
have
improved
Fed
transparency.
Due
to
the
lagged
release
of
meeting
transcripts,we
can
simultaneously
observe
the
SEP,
press
conferences,
and
meeting
transcripts
only
from
20113through
2017.
These
years
were
mostly
characterized
by
the
zero
lower
bound
(ZLB)
and
explicitforward
guidance,
both
of
which
e?ectively
reduce
the
scope
for
market
expectation
errors.
Evalu-ating
the
e?ects
of
the
SEP
and
press
conferences
would
require
more
post-ZLB
meeting
transcriptsto
be
released.
Second,
our
results
do
not
consider
the
possibility
that
FOMC
members
could
re-spond
to
enhanced
transparency
by
altering
the
content
discussed
at
monetary
policy
meetings.These
behavioral
responses
are
emphasized
in
Hansen,
McMahon
and
Prat
(2018),
who
study
theresponse
of
policymakers
to
the
transparency-enhancing
reforms
in
1993.The
asymmetry
we
?nd
between
tightening
and
easing
cycles
is
consistent
with
the
results
ofCieslak
(2018)
and
Schmeling,
Schrimpf
and
Ste?ensen
(2022),
who
?nd
large
excess
returns
inTreasuries
and
fed
funds
futures
during
easing
cycles,
but
not
during
tightening
cycles.
They
at-tribute
the
excess
returns
to
market
expectation
errors,
rather
than
to
changing
risk
premia.
Cieslak(2018)
argues
that
while
these
forecasting
errors
may
be
predictable
ex-post,
they
are
di?cult
topredict
in
real-time,
even
for
policymakers.
Other
papers
?nding
asymmetries
in
monetary
policyexpectations
between
tightening
and
easing
cycles
include
Bauer,
P?ueger
and
Sunderam
(2022),who
?nd
that
professional
forecasters
perceive
policy
decisions
to
be
less
dependent
on
macroe-conomic
conditions
during
easing
cycles
and
therefore
less
predictable.We
also
contribute
to
a
long-standing
literature
on
Fed
transparency.
Most
work
on
trans-parency
and
central
bank
communication
has
studied
the
optimal
level
of
transparency
and
theconditions
under
which
signaling
the
path
of
future
rates
is
welfare-enhancing.3
Less
work
hasbeen
done
on
the
extent
to
which
the
Fed
achieves
transparency
in
practice.
We
?ll
this
gap
byempirically
testing
the
extent
to
which
markets
could
have
historically
improved
their
policy
rateforecasting
with
broader
access
to
information
from
central
bank
meetings.Many
prior
studies
of
central
bank
transparency
have
focused
on
relative
improvements
intransparency.
For
example,
Swanson
(2006)
?nds
that
the
private
sector
has
become
better
at
fore-casting
monetary
policy
since
the
1980s,
likely
due
to
improved
Fed
transparency.
But
these
studiescan
only
measure
relative
changes
in
transparency
and
cannot
tell
us
how
transparent
communica-tions
are
overall.
The
only
studies
that
attempt
to
measure
central
bank
transparency
in
an
absolutesense
rely
on
a
qualitative
lens,
such
as
Eij?nger
and
Geraats
(2006)
and
Dincer
and
Eichengreen(2018),
who
develop
qualitative
indices
of
transparency
over
time
for
central
banks
around
the3For
details,
see
Woodford
(2005),
Cukierman
(2009),
Morris
and
Shin
(2005),
among
others.4world.
While
these
indices
are
useful
for
comparing
a
very
diverse
set
of
institutions,
they
rely
oncoarse
binary
criteria.Our
second
set
of
results
identi?es
the
speci?c
pieces
of
information
within
meeting
transcriptsand
Tealbooks
that
explain
the
large
gaps
between
the
FedSpeak
model’s
predictions
and
marketexpectations
during
easing
cycles.
We
generate
variable
importance
measures
from
the
FedSpeakmodel
to
determine
which
pieces
of
information
within
meeting
deliberations
would
have
beenmost
valuable
for
policy-sensitive
rate
markets
to
have
known
in
real-time.
In
2007-2008,
the
mostimportant
variables
were
?nancial
stability
topic
frequency,
?nancial
stability
sentiment,
economicgrowth
sentiment,
and
the
sentiment
of
the
FOMC’s
leadership.
In
2000-2003,
the
most
importantvariables
were
aggregate
sentiment,
economic
growth
sentiment,
and
the
sentiment
of
leadership.In
both
periods,
the
importance
of
these
variables
often
far
surpassed
the
importance
of
marketexpectations.We
interpret
the
variable
importance
results
through
the
lens
of
a
simple
monetary
policy
rule,where
the
future
fed
funds
rate
is
determined
by
the
committee’s
economic
outlook
and
a
time-varying
reaction
function.
According
to
Nakamura
and
Steinsson
(2018),
Campbell,
Evans
andJustiniano
(2012),
and
Romer
and
Romer
(2000),
the
Fed
has
an
“information
advantage”
aboutthe
economy
and
can
therefore
make
better
forecasts
than
the
public
about
future
economic
condi-tions.
Based
on
this
view,
the
FedSpeak
model
might
outperform
the
market
because
the
meetingmaterials
contain
important
information
about
the
Fed’s
economic
forecasts.The
view
that
the
Fed
has
stronger
forecasting
abilities
than
market
participants
has
been
chal-lenged
by
Hoesch,
Rossi
and
Sekhposyan
(forthcoming)
and
Bauer
and
Swanson
(2023),
amongothers,
who
?nd
that
Tealbook
forecasts
have
not
been
more
accurate
than
private
sector
forecastsin
recent
years.
Consistent
with
these
?ndings,
we
show
that
Tealbook
forecasts
were
relativelyunimportant
within
the
FedSpeak
model
during
easing
cycles
and
pointed
towards
tighter
policyrather
than
looser
policy.
Since
Tealbook
forecasts
are
commonly
assumed
within
the
literature
tore?ect
the
FOMC’s
economic
outlook
(see,
for
example,
Shapiro
and
Wilson
(2019)
and
Bauer
andSwanson
(2023)),
the
low
importance
of
these
forecasts
suggests
that
outlook-related
informationwas
unlikely
to
be
responsible
for
reduced
transparency
during
easing
cycles.As
an
additional
test
of
the
importance
of
outlook-related
information,
we
re-estimate
the
Fed-Speak
model
under
a
hypothetical
scenario
where
the
Fed
has
perfect
foresight
of
future
economic5conditions.
We
modify
the
FedSpeak
model
to
include
macroeconomic
data
releases,
like
nonfarmpayrolls
and
CPI
in?ation,
from
the
month
after
meeting
t.
Even
with
such
extreme
assumptionsabout
the
Fed’s
knowledge
of
the
economy,
the
topic
and
sentiment
variables
retain
at
least
75%of
their
predictive
power.
This
suggests
that
the
text-derived
variables
are
capturing
informationunrelated
to
the
state
of
the
economy
and
are
thus
providing
information
about
policymakers’reactions
to
incoming
economic
news.We
?nd
that
sentiment
and
topic
frequency
variables
are
often
more
important
than
marketexpectations
for
forecasting
future
policy
during
easing
cycles,
providing
a
compelling
a?rmativecase
for
a
reaction
function-based
explanation
of
easing
cycle
opacity.
Sentiment
is
important
be-cause
it
allows
us
to
directly
observe
the
reactions
of
FOMC
members
to
incoming
economic
datarather
than
having
to
infer
their
reaction
based
on
historical
relationships
between
macroeconomicvariables
and
monetary
policy.
Topic
frequency
variables
should
also
be
interpreted
as
related
tothe
reaction
function.
Holding
topic-speci?c
sentiment
constant,
if
the
FOMC
discusses
a
certaintopic
more
often,
then
the
members
may
implicitly
be
weighting
that
topic
more
heavily
in
theirreaction
function.Our
results
emphasizing
incomplete
information
about
policymakers’
reactions
are
consistentwith
a
growing
literature.
Bauer
and
Swanson
(2023)
propose
a
“Fed
response
to
news”
channelfor
explaining
monetary
policy
surprises.
Schmeling,
Schrimpf
and
Ste?ensen
(2022)
?nd
thatmarket
expectation
errors
occur
contemporaneously
with
Taylor
Rule
deviations.
Cieslak
(2018)?nds
that
a
large
portion
of
unexpected
easing
comes
from
unscheduled
FOMC
meetings,
suggest-ing
that
FOMC
members
eased
more
aggressively
than
markets
expected
in
response
to
surpriseeconomic
news.
Bauer,
P?ueger
and
Sunderam
(2022)
?nd
that
professional
forecasters
updatetheir
beliefs
about
the
Fed’s
reaction
function
in
response
to
monetary
policy
shocks,
indicatingimperfect
information
about
the
reaction
function.
We
contribute
to
this
literature
by
providingthe
?rst
quantitative
evidence
of
the
magnitude
of
these
information
frictions.A
reaction
function-based
explanation
of
the
FedSpeak
model’s
performance
has
quite
di?erentimplications
for
Fed
transparency
policy
than
a
forecast
or
outlook-based
explanation.
Informa-tion
about
forecasts
may
be
relatively
easy
to
convey
to
market
participants,
through
instrumentslike
the
Summary
of
Economic
Projections.
But
as
Woodford
(2005)
emphasizes,
conveying
infor-mation
about
the
Fed’s
reaction
function
to
the
public
is
di?cult
because
of
the
large
number
of6di?erent
contingencies
and
scenarios
that
may
arise,
each
demanding
a
di?erent
response
from
thecentral
bank.
The
easing
cycles
that
we
emphasize
may
be
examples
of
infrequent
contingencies,where
conveying
information
about
the
Fed’s
response
in
advance
may
be
di?cult
in
practice.
Ina
similar
vein,
Schmeling,
Schrimpf
and
Ste?ensen
(2022)
argue
that
the
Fed’s
response
to
nega-tive
macroeconomic
shocks
is
inherently
di?cult
for
markets
to
learn
because
of
the
relatively
fewobservations.Finally,
we
contribute
to
a
large
literature
that
uses
textual
analysis
of
FOMC
documents
andcommunications
to
study
FOMC
communications
and
the
transmission
of
communications
to
?-nancial
markets.
Some
important
papers
include
Hansen
and
McMahon
(2016),
Acosta
(2015),Gardner,
Scotti
and
Vega
(2022),
Schmanski
et
al.
(2023),
Chernulich,
Li
and
McGinn
(forthcom-ing),
and
Hansen
and
Kazinnik
(2023).The
rest
of
the
paper
proceeds
as
follows:
in
Section
2,
we
discuss
the
text
analysis
methodsused
to
summarize
the
qualitative
content
of
Fed
documents.
In
Section
3,
we
describe
the
con-struction
of
the
FedSpeak
model
and
show
its
superior
forecasting
ability
relative
to
market
ex-pectations.
In
Section
4,
we
use
variable
importance
measures
to
argue
that
market
forecastingerrors
during
easing
cycles
were
due
to
incomplete
information
about
the
FOMC’s
reaction
func-tion
rather
than
the
economic
outlook.
Section
5
o?ers
concluding
remarks.2
Text
Analysis
MethodologyIn
this
section,
we
describe
the
text
analysis
methods
we
use
for
topic
classi?cation
and
sentimentanalysis.
We
de?ne
topic
as
the
subject
of
a
speaker’s
sentence,
as
it
relates
to
the
economy
ormonetary
policy.
For
example,
in
the
phrase
“market
liquidity
is
worsening”,
the
topic
is
clearlymarket
functioning,
or
?nancial
stability
more
broadly.
In
the
phrase,
“the
CPI
release
shows
mixedsignals”,
the
topic
is
clearly
in?ation.We
de?ne
sentiment
as
the
subjective
attitude
that
a
speaker
conveys
through
their
language.For
example,
the
phrase
“market
liquidity
is
worsening”
conveys
negative
sentiment
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 供熱公司收購合同范本
- 買方單方面違約合同范本
- 上海租賃牌照合同范本
- 2024年遵義市赤水市公益性崗位人員招聘考試真題
- Unit 1 A new start:Understanding ideas ① 教學(xué)設(shè)計 -2024-2025學(xué)年外研版(2024年)英語七年級 上冊
- 出售大型廢船合同范本
- 臨時供電協(xié)議合同范本
- 2024年民主與科學(xué)雜志社招聘考試真題
- 勞務(wù)合同范本修灶臺
- 上海疫情物質(zhì)供貨合同范本
- 行為矯正原理與方法課件
- 《人工智能導(dǎo)論》(第2版)高職全套教學(xué)課件
- 39 《出師表》對比閱讀-2024-2025中考語文文言文閱讀專項訓(xùn)練(含答案)
- 蛇膽川貝液在動物模型中的藥理作用研究
- GB/T 44260-2024虛擬電廠資源配置與評估技術(shù)規(guī)范
- 中國煤炭地質(zhì)總局公開招聘報名表
- AQ 1064-2008 煤礦用防爆柴油機無軌膠輪車安全使用規(guī)范(正式版)
- 電子商務(wù)數(shù)據(jù)分析基礎(chǔ)(第二版) 課件 模塊1、2 電子商務(wù)數(shù)據(jù)分析概述、基礎(chǔ)數(shù)據(jù)采集
- YB-T+4190-2018工程用機編鋼絲網(wǎng)及組合體
- 高大模板安全施工施工安全保證措施
- 比亞迪公司應(yīng)收賬款管理的問題及對策分析
評論
0/150
提交評論