版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請進(jìn)行舉報或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡介
PublicDisclosureAuthorizedPublicDisclosureAuthorized
PolicyResearchWorkingPaper10956
FadingAwayInformalitybyDevelopment
M.Naz?mTamko?
WORLDBANKGROUP
DevelopmentEconomicsGlobalIndicatorsGroupOctober2024
PolicyResearchWorkingPaper10956
Abstract
Thispaperfocusesontheroleofdevelopmentininfor-malitythroughhigherwagesandexpandedproductionpossibilities.First,itusesinformal,plant-levelsurveydataacrosscountriestodocumentthatonaverage,richercoun-trieshavesmallerinformal,unregisteredplantsintermsofemployment.Thisnegativerelationshipholdsevenaftercontrollingforplant-levelcharacteristics.Then,adynamicgeneralequilibriummodelwithincompletetaxenforcementisdevelopedsuchthatformalandinformalplantscoexistinequilibrium.Themodelallowsfortwogroupsofagentsoperatingintheinformalsector:thosewithlowerabilities
thanworkers,andthosewithabilitiesfallingbetweenworkersandformalmanagers.Inthemodel,whenplantsbecomemoreproductive,someagentsoperatinginformallychoosetobeworkersandsomeofthemtransitionintoformalityduetohigherwagesandbetterproductionpos-sibilities,whichdecreasesthemeansizeofinformalplants.Thequantitativeresultsindicatethataround30percentoftheincreaseinaggregateoutputduetohigherproductivityisassociatedwitharoughlyone-quarterdeclineinthemeansizeofinformalplants.
ThispaperisaproductoftheGlobalIndicatorsGroup,DevelopmentEconomics.ItispartofalargereffortbytheWorldBanktoprovideopenaccesstoitsresearchandmakeacontributiontodevelopmentpolicydiscussionsaroundtheworld.PolicyResearchWorkingPapersarealsopostedontheWebat
/prwp
.Theauthormaybecontactedatmtamkoc@.
ThePolicyResearchWorkingPaperSeriesdisseminatesthefindingsofworkinprogresstoencouragetheexchangeofideasaboutdevelopmentissues.Anobjectiveoftheseriesistogetthefindingsoutquickly,evenifthepresentationsarelessthanfullypolished.Thepaperscarrythenamesoftheauthorsandshouldbecitedaccordingly.Thefindings,interpretations,andconclusionsexpressedinthispaperareentirelythoseoftheauthors.TheydonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheInternationalBankforReconstructionandDevelopment/WorldBankanditsaffiliatedorganizations,orthoseoftheExecutiveDirectorsoftheWorldBankorthegovernmentstheyrepresent.
ProducedbytheResearchSupportTeam
FadingAwayInformalitybyDevelopment*
M.Naz?mTamko??
October2024
Forthelatestversion,pleaseclickhere
Keywords:Informality,EconomicDevelopment,PlantSize,Productivity
JELClassification:E23,J24,L25,O41,O33
*IwouldliketothankJuheeBae,FilipJolevski,NormanLoayza,HibretMaemir,JorgeRodriguezMeza,FurkanSarikayaandGustavoVenturafortheircommentsandsuggestions.Thefindings,interpretations,andconclusionsexpressedinthispaperareentirelythoseoftheauthors.TheydonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsoftheWorldBankanditsaffiliatedorganizations,orthoseoftheExecutiveDirectorsoftheWorldBankorthegovernmentstheyrepresent.
?TheWorldBank,EnterpriseAnalysisUnitE-Mail:mtamkoc@
1
1Introduction
Informality,economicactivityoutsideofformalregulationsandinstitutionalframeworks,isoftenseenasacommonfeatureofdevelopingcountries.1Theliteraturehasfocusedonreducinginformalitythroughstrengtheningenforcementofpoliciesandloweringthecostsofoperatingformally,suchastaxratesandentryfees.However,developedcountriesdon’thaveoversightofalleconomicactivities,andtheirtaxratescanbeashighasindevelopingcountries.2Thispaperarguesthathigherlevelofinformalityinpoorercountriesisnotonlytheresultofburdensomeregulationsorinadequateenforcement,butalsoabyproductofunderdevelopment.
Inrichercountrieswithbetterproductiontechnologiesandeconomicenvironments,someworkerspreferformalwageemploymentoveroperatinganinformalbusiness,aswageratesarehigher.Likewise,somemanagersoptforformalfirmregistrationandoperationbe-causetheincomepotentialinrichermarketsmakesformalitymoreprofitabledespitethecostsoftaxesandregulations.
Inthispaper,Ifocusontheincidenceofinformalityattheextensivemargin,referringtounregisteredplants.Istartbydocumentingempiricalfactsrelatedwithinformalityinthedevelopingworld.Usingplant-leveldatafromtheWorldBankInformalSectorEnterpriseSurveys(ISES),Ishowthatinformalplantsinrichercountriestendtoemployfewerwork-ersonaveragethaninformalplantsinpoorercountries.Inotherwords,theinformalmeansizedecreaseswiththelevelofdevelopment.Forexample,informalplantsinGhanahave2.3workersonaverage,whereasinPeru,informalplantsaverageonly1.4workers.ThisnegativerelationshipbetweeninformalplantsizeandGDPpercapitapersistsevenaftercontrollingforplantcharacteristicssuchasmanagers’education,experience,andgender,sectorofac-tivity,andplantage.Moreover,whilesomeinformalplantsachieveproductivitylevels,mea-suredbyvalue-addedperworker,comparabletotheirformalcounterparts,mostoperateatverylowlevels.
Toquantifytheimpactofdevelopmentoninformality,Idevelopadynamic-generalequi-libriummodelofoccupationalchoicewhereagentsareoptimallyallocatedasworkersormanagersaccordingtotheirabilitiesinthespiritofLucas(1978)’sspan-of-controlmodelbasedonPoschke(2018).Inthemodel,whileworkers’earningsareproportionaltotheirabilities,managerialearningsareincreasinginreturnstotheirabilities.Iintroduceinfor-
1SeeDeSoto(1989),andLaPorta&Shleifer(2014),Ulyssea(2020)andOhnsorge&Yu(2022)forasurveyofinformalityliterature.
2SeeFriedmanetal.(2000)forthenegativerelationshipbetweentaxratesandinformality.
2
malitybyallowingmanagerstooperateinformallytoavoidtaxationduetoincompleteen-forcement.Theyriskbeingcaughtiftheyusecapitaloveracertainthreshold,similartoDeSoto(1989)andLeal(2014).Inequilibrium,agentsatthelowerendoftheabilitydistribu-tionoperateasinformalmanagers.Agentswithabilitieshigherthanthoseofinformalman-agers,butnothighenoughtorunplants,becomeworkers.Ifenforcementlimitsortaxesarenotexcessivelylow,informalitymayalsoexistamongagentswithabilitiesexceedingthoseofworkers.Ofthesehigher-abilityagents,therelativelylessableoperateinformally,whilethemoreablerunformalplants.Informalmanagerswithabilitieslowerthanworkersarere-ferredtoasoperatinginsubsistenceinformality.Inthecasethatenforcementlimitsortaxesaresufficientlylow,allagentswithabilitieshigherthanworkersoperateintheformalsector.
Icalibratekeymodelparameterstomatchplantsizedistribution,includinginformalplantsinGhana.Themodelsuccessfullygeneratestheobservedmeanplantsizedifferencesbetweenformalandinformalsectors.Inthebenchmarkeconomy,while90.6%ofplantsareinformal,theyaccountfor34.2%ofaggregateoutput.Moreover,71.1%ofinformalplantsoperateatthesubsistenceinformalitylevel.Hence,theaverageinformalmanagerearnslessthantheaverageworker.
Motivatedbybetterbusinessenvironmentsandhigheryearsofschoolinginrichercoun-tries,developmentisintroducedintothemodelsuchthatallmanagers’productivityin-creases.Asaresult,relativelyhigher-abilityinformalplantmanagersstartoperatingformallysince,oncemoreproductive,theydemandmorelaborandcapital.Incontrast,relativelylower-abilityinformalplantmanagersswitchtobecomeworkersinthenewequilibrium,enjoyinghigherwages.Therefore,whileinformalitydecreaseswithdevelopment,theshareofsubsistenceinformalityincreasesamonginformalplants.
Quantitativelywhentheaggregateoutputincreasesbyabout29.5%duetoimprovementsinmanagers’productivity,theoverallaverageplantsizeincreasesby30%whereasthemeaninformalplantsizedeclinesbyabout26.1%.Whenthemodelisdisciplinedtoaccountfordifferencesininformalmeanplantsizeacrosscountries,itcanexplain32.8%ofincomepercapitadifferencesonaverage.Moreover,whenonlytheformalsectorbenefitsfrompropor-tionalandskill-biasedimprovementsinthemanagers’productivity,theshareofinformalplantsshrinks,andtheoverallmeansizegrowsfastercomparedtothecasewhereallman-agersbenefitfromdevelopment.Thepaperconcludesbycomparingthegainsfromformal-izationpolicies,suchasbetterenforcementandlowertaxes:whileformalizationpolicieshavethepotentialtodecreaseinformality,theirgainsarelimitedcomparedtothegainsfromhigherproductivityassociatedwithimprovingthebusinessenvironmentandimprovinged-ucationlevels.
3
BackgroundTheinformalityliteraturegrewextensivelyfollowingDeSoto(1989).First,LaPorta&Shleifer(2008)andLaPorta&Shleifer(2014)areamongtheearlieststudiesthatutilizesISEStodocumentdifferencesbetweenformalandinformalplants.Amin&Okou(2020)extendstheircomparisontoabroadersetofcountries.Icontributetothisliteraturebysystematicallyshowingthatinformalplantstendtobelargerinpoorercountries.
Second,Rauch(1991),Loayza(1996),Amaral&Quintin(2006),D’Erasmo&Boedo(2012),Leal(2014),Meghiretal.(2015),Ulyssea(2018)andFranjoetal.(2022)developenviron-mentswhereinformalityexistsduetotheminimumwages,incompleteenforcementandfrictionsinaccessingfinance.IextendthemodelofPoschke(2018)byallowinginformalitytoexistendogenouslyduetotheincompleteenforcementoftaxes.Inthemodel,agentssortintobeingworkers,informalmanagers,andformalmanagers.Mycontributionisprovidinganenvironmentwhereagentswithabilitieslowerthanworkers(subsistenceinformality)aswellasthosewithhigherabilitiesbecomeinformalmanagers.
Third,theaboveliteraturefocusesontheformalizationpoliciessuchasreducingthecostofbeingformalortaxes,motivatedbyJohnsonetal.(1998),Fajnzylberetal.(2011),DeMeletal.(2013),Bruhn&McKenzie(2014),DeAndradeetal.(2016)andRochaetal.(2018)amongmanyothers;andincreasingenforcementasinKuehn(2014),Orsietal.(2014),Leal(2014)andUlyssea(2018).However,inthispaper,Iquantifytheroleofdevelopmentinre-ducinginformality.Loayza(2016)studieshowgrowthratesandmigrationaffectinformalityinagrowth-accountingsetup,andprojectslaborinformalityovertwodecades.Thispaperdiffersbydevelopingaspan-of-controlmodelwithheterogeneousproductionunitsanddis-cipliningthemodelusingaplantsizedistributionincludinginformality.
Lastly,thispapercontributestotheliteraturestudyingplant-levelproductivity,size,andaggregateproductivity,advancedbyHsieh&Klenow(2009),Bartelsmanetal.(2013)andHsieh&Klenow(2014).Bento&Restuccia(2017)andBento&Restuccia(2021)documentthatrichercountrieshavelargerplantsintermsofemploymentonaverage.Restuccia&Rogerson(2008),Guneretal.(2008),Garcia-Santana&Pijoan-Mas(2014)andGourio&Roys(2014)havefocusedontheroleofsize-dependentdistortionsasoneofthemainreasonsforsmallerplantsinpoorercountries.Tamko?&Ventura(2024)studytimetaxes–rulesandregulationsthatdistortmanagers’productivetime–asadeterminantofsmallerplantsinpoorercountries,onaverage.Inthispaper,Istudytheprevalenceoflargerinformalplantsinunderdevelopedcountriesasonereasonforthesmalleroverallmeanplantsizeinthesecountries.
4
2Data
ThemaindatasourceofthispaperistheWorldBank’sISESwhichconsistsofface-to-faceinterviewswithownersormanagersofinformalplants.3Itusesanarea-basedsamplingmethodologythatgeneratesaprobabilisticsampleofinformalfirmswhereinterviewersenu-merateallplantsinarandomlyselecteduniformblocksinagivenregionorcitytodetermineregistrationstatus.Ifaplantisnotregisteredinthelocalregistrationinstitution,itiscon-sideredinformal.Withinselectedinformalplantsarerandomlyselectedinrealtimeforadeeperinterview.Varioustopicssuchasworkforce,sales,sectorandbackgroundofman-agersarecoveredinthequestionnaire.4ISESincludes25,995plant-levelobservationsfrom78regions/citiesin26countriessince2008.5ThePPPadjustedrealGDPpercapita,RGDP,andemploymentdatacomefromWorldDevelopmentIndicators(WDI).Thesamplecoverscountriesatdifferentlevelsofdevelopment:therichestcountryinthesampleisArgentinawhereasDemocraticRepublicoftheCongohasthelowestRGDPpercapitacomparedtoothercountriesinthesample.
Thenumberofworkersinaninformalplantisthetotalnumberofpaidandunpaidwork-ers.Figure1presentsthemainmotivatingfactofthepaper:richercountriestendtohavesmallerinformalplantsonaverage.Inthefigure,eachdotrepresentsacountry.They-axisandx-axisaretheaveragenumberofworkersininformalplantsandtheRGDPpercapitaineachcountryrespectively.Forexample,theaverageinformalplantinArgentinahas1.6workers,whileinGhanaandNepal,theaveragesare2.3and4.1workersperinformalplant,respectively.
ThesolidlineinFigure1isthesimplelinearregressionlinewherethelog-informalmeansizeisregressedonthelog-RGDPpercapitawhereobservationsareweightedaccordingtotheiremploymentsize.Despitethesmallsamplesize,theelasticityoftheinformalmeansizewithrespecttoRGDPpercapitaisnegativeandstatisticallysignificant.ItimpliesthatdoublingRGDPpercapitaisassociatedwith29.3%declineininformalmeansize.
ThefollowingregressionequationisestimatedtotestwhetherthenegativerelationshipbetweentheinformalmeansizeandtheRGDPpercapitapersistsaftercontrollingforplant
3Forplant-leveldatasetsandfurtherinformationaboutthemethodology,pleasevisit
4After2015,ISESusesanadaptiveclustersamplingmethodologywhichenablesthecomputationoftheprobabilityofselectionofaplantwithinablock,thusallowingtheuseofsamplingweightstomakeinferencestothepopulationofinformalbusinesseswiththeregion/city.SeeAgaetal.(2023)andAberraetal.(2022).
5PleaseseeAppendixBforthelistofcountriesandthenumberofobservations.
5
characteristics.
log?Sizei,c¢=β0+β1log(RGDPc)+Xi,c+?i,c(1)
whereSizei,cisthenumberofworkersinplantiincountrycandRGDPcistheRGDPpercapitaincountryc.Xi,cincludesplantcharacteristicvariablesinplantiincountryc.Itconsistsofamanufacturingdummy;aneducationofamanagerdummywhichis1ifthehighestlevelofamanagerisatleastsecondaryschool;experienceofamanagerinthesector(inyears);afemaledummywhichtakesvalue1ifthemanagerisfemale;andtheageoftheplant(inyears,asofthedateofinterview).
Table1presentstheestimatedcoefficientsoftheEquation(1).Theelasticityoftheinfor-malmeansizewithrespecttoRGDPpercapitais-0.16andsignificantevenaftercontrollingforallplantcharacteristics.Inaddition,theestimationresultsindicatethatinformalplantsoperatinginthemanufacturingsectorsignificantlyemploymoreworkersthanthoseoper-atingintheservicessectoronaverage.Moreover,theexperienceandeducationofmanagersispositivelycorrelatedwiththesizeofinformalplants.Ontheotherhand,plantsmanagedbyafemalemanageraresignificantlysmallercomparedtoplantsmanagedbyamale.
Next,Icompareinformalplantsvis-a-visformalplantsinGhana.6WorldBankEnterpriseSurveys(WBES)conductedtwoothersurveysinGhanain2013alongwithISES:Micro-WBESandWBES.Onlyformal(registered)plantsarecoveredinbothsurveys.Micro-WBESinter-viewsplantswithfewerthan5workers,whileWBESinterviewsplantswithatleast5workers.IrefertoplantsinbothMicro-WBESandWBESasformalplants.
Table2presentsthecomparisonofinformalandformalplantsinGhana.Themeansizeofinformalplantsissmallerthanformalplants:thereare2.3workersininformalplantswhereas3and34.7workersareinvolvedinproductionintheMicro-WBESandWBESre-spectively.7Moreover,informalmanagershavelessexperienceinthesectortheyoperateincomparedtoformalmanagers.While42.8%ofinformalmanagershaveatleastasecondaryschooldegree,around65%ofworkersinformalplantshaveatleastasecondaryschoolde-gree.Tosumup,onaverage,informalplantsaresmallerandyoungercomparedtoformalplants;theirmanagershavefewerexperienceandlesseducation;thefractionoffemaleman-agersishigheramonginformalplants.
6SimilaranalysisisdonebyLaPorta&Shleifer(2014)acrossafewcountriesusingthesamedataset,andMeghiretal.(2015)andUlyssea(2018)inBrazil.
7AsSection4discussesindetail,theGhanaStatisticalService’sIntegratedBusinessEstablishmentSurveyreportsthemeansizeofinformalplantsas2.3workersandthemeansizeofformalplantsas33.8.SimilarmeansizesoftheWorldBank’splantlevelsurveydatasetswiththatoftheGhanaStatisticalService’scensusbuildconfidenceintheusageofISESandWBEStocompareinformalandformalplantsinGhana.
6
Finally,IfocusonproductivitydifferencesbetweeninformalandformalplantsinGhana.8Figure2plotsthedistributionofLog-VAperworkerinISES,Micro-WBESandWBES.Therearethreeobservationsrelatedwiththeproductivitydifferencesbetweeninformalandformalplants.First,asTable2alsoshows,informalplantsarelessproductivecomparedtoformalplants.Secondly,whilemostproductiveinformalplantsaresimilartomostunproductiveformalplantsintermsofproductivitylevels,therearesomeinformalplantsthatoperateatverylowlevels.Third,informalplantshavelongleft-tailproductivitywhereasformalplantshavelongright-tailproductivity.
3Model
ThemodelisbasedonPoschke(2018).Theinnovationinthispaperisthatmanagerscanoperateintheinformalsectortoavoiddistortions.
3.1Environment
Thereisahouseholdwithacontinuumofhouseholdmembers.Eachhouseholdmemberisbornwithaunitofefficiency,zandaunitoftimesuppliedinelastically.TheunitofefficiencyisdistributedaccordingtoacdfG(z)over[0,]andisreferredasabilityinthispaper.Thehouseholdhasapreferenceoveraconsumptiongoodanddiscountsthefutureattherate
β<1:
∞
βtlog(2)
Ateachperiod,householdmembersareassignedtobeworkersormanagersbasedontheirabilities.Workerssupplytheirabilitytocollectwages.Managersrunplantstoproducethesinglefinalgoodoftheeconomybyhiringworkersandrentingcapital.Productionofthefinalgoodrequiresrunningdifferentiatedactivitiesi.e.,usingintermediategoods.FollowingPoschke(2018),thenumberofactivitiesthatamanagerwithabilityzcanperform,M(z),
equalstozwhere>1representstheaggregatetechnologylevel.Irefertothenumber
ofactivitiesamanagercanperformasproductivitythroughoutthepaper.
8Productivityismeasuredbythelogofvalueadded(Log-VA)perworkerandVAisdefinedassalesminusexpendituresonrawmaterialsandenergyfollowingLaPorta&Shleifer(2008).
7
Thefinaloutputofaplant,y,withamanagerofabilityzcanbedefinedasfollows:
wherejdenotesdifferentactivities,njandkjaretheamountofabilityandcapitalusedinactivityjrespectively,1>α>0istheimportanceoflaborinproduction,1>γ>0isthespan-of-controlparameterandσ>1istheelasticityofsubstitutionbetweendifferentiatedproducts.
Governmentcollectstaxesfromoutputattherateτ.EnforcementoftaxcollectionisincompleteinthesensethatmanagerscanoperateinformallytoavoidtaxesinlinewithLeal(2014).However,thereisapossibilitythataninformalmanagercangetcaughtwithprobability,p(kj):
whereBrepresentstheenforcementlevelsuchthatifamanagerusesmorecapitalthanBintheproductionofthefinalgood,shewillbecaught.Therefore,managerscanavoidtaxesbylimitingtheircapitaltolessthanorequaltoBintotal.Ifamanageriscaughtwhileoperatinginformally,shelosesallprofits.
ProblemofanInformalManagerAmanagerwithabilityzwhooperatesinformallychoosestheamountofcapitalandlabortomaximizeherprofit,πI(z):
whereWandRarewagesandrentalrateofcapitalrespectively.
ProblemofaFormalManagerAmanagerwithabilityzwhooperatesformallychoosestheamountofcapitalandlabortomaximizeherprofit,πF(z).Sincethemanageroperatesformally,itsoutputissubjecttoatax,τ.
8
Thegovernmentcollectstaxesfromformalmanagersandreturnsthemtothehouseholdasalump-sumtransfereveryperiod:
Tt=Gt?t(7)
whereTtdenotesthetransferstothehouseholdandGtisthegovernmentrevenuefromtaxation.
ProblemoftheHouseholdThehouseholdassignsitsmemberstothreeoccupations:work-ers,informalmanagersandformalmanagers,andchoosesitsconsumption,Ctandhowmuchcapitaltocarryouttothenextperiod,Kt+1inordertomaximizeitslife-timeutility:
s.t.
Ct+Kt+1=It(SW,t,SI,t,SF,t,Wt,Rt)+(1?δ+Rt)Kt+Tt
whereSW,t,SI,t,SF,tdenotethesetofworkers,informalmanagersandformalmanagersre-spectively,δisthedepreciationrateofthecapital,TtisthetransferfromgovernmentandIt(SW,t,SI,t,SF,t,Wt,Rt)isthetotalincomeofhouseholdmembers:
wherethefirstitemoftheright-handsideisthewageincomeofworkersandthesecondandthethirditemsrepresentthetotalprofitoftheinformalandformalmanagersrespectively.9
3.2PropertiesoftheEquilibrium
Thissectionfocusesonastationaryequilibriumanddiscussesitskeyfeatures.Profitofaformalmanagerwithabilityz,πF(z),canbewrittenasafunctionofparametersandinputpricesusingequations(A.3)and(A.4):
9AppendixAprovidesthefirst-orderconditionsofmanagers’problemsandthedefinitionofequilibrium.
9
AllinformalmanagerslimittheircapitalusagetoBorlessintheirplants,astheywouldbecaughtoperatinginformallyotherwise.Then,theprofitofaninformalmanagerwithabilityz,πI(z),canbewrittenasafunctionofparametersusingequations(A.5),(A.6),(A.7)and(A.8):
(11)
Iassumethatγ>>αsuchthatprofitfunctionsofbothtypesofmanagersarein-creasingandconvexinz.Thisassumptionalsoguaranteestheexistenceanduniquenessoftheequilibriumwhereinformalandformalmanagerscoexist(givenhighτandB).Ifthe
totalamountofcapitalusedinaninformalplantislessthanB,theπIisstrictlygreaterthan
πFdueto<1.ThehighestamountofcapitalthataninformalmanageruseisB.IrefertoinformalmanagerswhouseexactlyBamountofcapitalasconstrainedinformalmanagers.Theycanstillincreasetheirprofitbyhiringmorelaborgiventheirconstrainedcapital.Asaresult,theslopeofinformalmanagers’profit,πI(z),isaffected.Whentheop-timalamountofcapitalforaninformalmanagerisequaltoB,theslopeoftheinformalmanager’sprofitwithrespecttozbecomessmallerthanthatoftheformalmanager’sprofitfunction.Then,πIcancrossπFatmostoncebecausebothfunctionsarestrictlyincreasing.Sinceworkers’earningsincreaseproportionaltotheirability,thisestablishestheexistenceanduniqueness.
Figure3describesanequilibriumassignmentofhouseholdmemberstodifferentoc-cupations.Thehorizontalaxisrepresentsabilitiesandtheverticalaxisistheearningsofhouseholdmembers.WhileπI(z),thesolidline,andπF(z),thedash-dottedline,areincreas-ingandconvexwheretheycrosseachotheronlyonce,theearningsofworkers,thedashedline,islinearandincreasingwithaslopeofW.Householdmemberswithz∈[0,z)andz∈[z,z)becomeinformalmanagers,householdmemberswithabilityz∈[z,]becomeformalmanagersandremaininghouseholdmemberswithabilityz∈[z,z)assignedtobeworkersinthisequilibrium.Thesubsistenceinformalityexistswherez∈[0,z).Iftaxesarelowortheenforcementisstricter(i.e.lowB)inaneconomy,theremaybeonlysubsistenceinformalityintheequilibrium.Inotherwords,z,theabilitylevelwheretheinformalprofitfunctioncrossestheformalprofitfunction,canbesmallerthanz,thethresholdlevelwheretheearningslineofworkerscrossestheprofitofmanagersfromabove.
Thesolutiontothemanagers’probleminAppendixAshowsthattheamountofcapital
10
andlabordevotedtoeachactivityisthesameacrossactivitiesforagivenmanager.There-fore,Iexpressthecapital-laborratioattheactivitylevelwithoutlossofgenerality.Usingequations(A.3)and(A.4),thecapital-laborratioofformalmanagerscanbewrittenasfol-lows:
(12)
Similarly,thecapital-laborratioofinformalmanagerscanalsobederivedusingequations(A.5),(A.6),(A.7)and(A.8)asfollows:
Noticethatcapital-laborratiosofformalandinformalmanagersareconstantandequaltoeachotherifinformalmanagersoptimallychooselesscapitalthanB.However,moreable,constrained,informalmanagershaveasmallercapital-laborratiocomparedtoothermanagersandtheratiodecreaseswiththeabilityofinformalmanagersasγ>.
Sincemanagershireefficiencyunits,IdefinethesizeofaplantrelativetotheaverageabilityofworkersasinPoschke(2018).LetFPbethefractionofplants,i.e.thefractionofmanagers,whichisthesumofthefractionofformalmanagers,FF,andinformalmanagers,FI.Hence,themeansizeofinformalplantscanbedefinedastheratiooftheaverageabilitydemandedininformalplantsandtheaverageabilityofworkersininformalplants.Usingthemarketclearingcondition,itcanbewrittenasfollows
whereFWIistheshareofinformalworkersamongworkerssuchthatFWI(1?
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 二零二五年度PVC管道配件定制與銷售合同3篇
- 2024版鐵礦石采購合同
- 二零二五年度各類合同匯編:商業(yè)地產(chǎn)租賃訂金協(xié)議
- 二零二五年度鐵路貨物運輸安全責(zé)任保險合同細(xì)則
- 2025年度私募基金資金代持管理服務(wù)合同
- 2025年度未簽合同員工勞動仲裁處理及勞動權(quán)益保障合同
- 二零二五年度超市租賃合同排他性節(jié)假日顧客關(guān)系管理協(xié)議
- 2025年度終止商鋪租賃合同及租賃場地環(huán)境恢復(fù)及修復(fù)協(xié)議
- 南京交通職業(yè)技術(shù)學(xué)院《影視讀解》2023-2024學(xué)年第一學(xué)期期末試卷
- 南方科技大學(xué)《光纖通信系統(tǒng)》2023-2024學(xué)年第一學(xué)期期末試卷
- 軟件項目應(yīng)急措施及方案
- 2025河北邯鄲經(jīng)開國控資產(chǎn)運營管理限公司招聘專業(yè)技術(shù)人才5名高頻重點提升(共500題)附帶答案詳解
- 2024年民法典知識競賽考試題庫及答案(共50題)
- 2025老年公寓合同管理制度
- 2024-2025學(xué)年人教版數(shù)學(xué)六年級上冊 期末綜合卷(含答案)
- 鈑金設(shè)備操作培訓(xùn)
- 感染性腹瀉的護(hù)理查房
- 中考英語688高頻詞大綱詞頻表
- 九年級初三中考物理綜合復(fù)習(xí)測試卷3套(含答案)
- 管理制度評價表(填寫模板)
- 工地設(shè)計代表服務(wù)記錄
評論
0/150
提交評論