




版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
DEBTSHOCKS
ANDTHEDYNAMICS
OFOUTPUTANDINFLATIONINEMERGINGECONOMIES
JohnBeirneandNuobuRenzhi
NO.739
ADBECONOMICS
August2024
WORKINGPAPERSERIES
ASIANDEVELOPMENTBANK
ADBEconomicsWorkingPaperSeries
DebtShocksandtheDynamicsofOutputandInflationinEmergingEconomies
JohnBeirneandNuobuRenzhiNo.739|August2024
TheADBEconomicsWorkingPaperSeries
presentsresearchinprogresstoelicitcommentsandencouragedebateondevelopmentissuesinAsiaandthePacific.Theviewsexpressed
arethoseoftheauthorsanddonotnecessarilyreflecttheviewsandpoliciesofADBor
itsBoardofGovernorsorthegovernmentstheyrepresent.
JohnBeirne(jbeirne@)isaprincipaleconomistattheEconomicResearchandDevelopmentImpact
Department,AsianDevelopmentBank.NuobuRenzhi(renzhinuobu@)isanassistantprofessor
attheSchoolofEconomics,CapitalUniversityofEconomicsandBusiness.
ASIANDEVELOPMENTBANK
CreativeCommonsAttribution3.0IGOlicense(CCBY3.0IGO)
?2024AsianDevelopmentBank
6ADBAvenue,MandaluyongCity,1550MetroManila,PhilippinesTel+63286324444;Fax+63286362444
Somerightsreserved.Publishedin2024.
ISSN2313-6537(print),2313-6545(PDF)PublicationStockNo.WPS240396-2
DOI:
/10.22617/WPS240396-2
TheviewsexpressedinthispublicationarethoseoftheauthorsanddonotnecessarilyreflecttheviewsandpoliciesoftheAsianDevelopmentBank(ADB)oritsBoardofGovernorsorthegovernmentstheyrepresent.
ADBdoesnotguaranteetheaccuracyofthedataincludedinthispublicationandacceptsnoresponsibilityforany
consequenceoftheiruse.ThementionofspecificcompaniesorproductsofmanufacturersdoesnotimplythattheyareendorsedorrecommendedbyADBinpreferencetoothersofasimilarnaturethatarenotmentioned.
Bymakinganydesignationoforreferencetoaparticularterritoryorgeographicareainthisdocument,ADBdoesnotintendtomakeanyjudgmentsastothelegalorotherstatusofanyterritoryorarea.
ThispublicationisavailableundertheCreativeCommonsAttribution3.0IGOlicense(CCBY3.0IGO)
/licenses/by/3.0/igo/
.Byusingthecontentofthispublication,youagreetobeboundbythetermsofthislicense.Forattribution,translations,adaptations,andpermissions,pleasereadtheprovisionsandtermsofuseat
/terms-use#openaccess
.
ThisCClicensedoesnotapplytonon-ADBcopyrightmaterialsinthispublication.Ifthematerialisattributed
toanothersource,pleasecontactthecopyrightownerorpublisherofthatsourceforpermissiontoreproduceit.ADBcannotbeheldliableforanyclaimsthatariseasaresultofyouruseofthematerial.
Pleasecontactpubsmarketing@ifyouhavequestionsorcommentswithrespecttocontent,orifyouwishtoobtaincopyrightpermissionforyourintendedusethatdoesnotfallwithintheseterms,orforpermissiontousetheADBlogo.
CorrigendatoADBpublicationsmaybefoundat
/publications/corrigenda
.
ABSTRACT
Thispaperempiricallyexaminestheimpactofpublicdebtshocksonoutputandinflationin34emergingmarketeconomies(EMEs)usingpanellocalprojectionsovertheperiod2000to2022.Theestimatedresultsshowthatrealgrossdomesticproduct(GDP)fallssignificantlyafteranunanticipatedincreaseinpublicdebtwhileinflationrises.WealsoexaminewhetherfundamentalcharacteristicsacrossEMEscouldaffecttheimpactofpublicdebtshocks.Theresultssuggestthathigherinitialdebtlevels,tighterdomesticfinancialconditions,andlowerincomelevelsamplifythenegativeresponsesofrealGDP,whiletighterglobalfinancialconditionsdampenthenegativeimpactsofdebtshocks.Forinflation,theresponsesvarydependingoneconomic-specificcharacteristics.Wealso
findothernonlinearitiesinthedynamics,withEMEsfacingmoresevereeffectsduring
recessionaryperiods.
Keywords:publicdebt,GDP,inflation,emergingmarketeconomiesJELcodes:E62,F40
1.Introduction
Thelinkbetweendebtandtheoutlookforeconomicgrowthandinflationisakeypolicyconsideration.Debtsustainabilityrisksinemergingmarketeconomies(EMEs)wereamplifiedintheaftermathofthecoronavirusdisease(COVID-19)pandemic.Fiscalsupportpackagesimplementedduetothepandemicledtohigherstocksofpublicdebt,whiletighterglobalmonetaryconditionsincreasedthecostoffinancingpublicdebt,wideningdeficits.Managingtheinflationaryeffectsoffiscalexpansionshascreatedsignificantchallengesforpolicymakers,alsoaffectingthetrajectoryofoutputgrowth.ThispaperconsiderstheramificationsofdebtshocksinEMEsonthetrajectoryofoutputandinflationovershortandlongerhorizons.
Thispapercontributestotheliteratureonthemacroeconomiceffectsofdebt.Thereissignificantliteratureontheroleofdebtinaffectingoutput.ReinhartandRogoff(2010)notethatforlevelsofdebttogrossdomesticproduct(GDP)above90%,anegativeimpactongrowthmaterializes.Asregardstheroleofdebtoninflation,thiscanbetracedbacktothefiscaldominanceworkofSargentandWallace(1981),wherebypersistentfiscaldeficitsandexcessivedebtconstrainthecentralbankfromtighteningmonetarypolicy,leadingtoamplifiedinflationexpectations.CevikandMiryugin(2023)findthattheextentoffiscalpolicyshocksoninflationiscloselydrivenbytheinitialleveloffiscalspace.Buildingontheliterature,thispapersimultaneouslyexaminestheimpactofexogenousdebtshocksonoutputandinflation.ThispaperaimstofillthisgapintheliteraturebyemployingpanellocalprojectionsasinJordà(2005)toestimatetheimpactofpublicdebtonoutputandinflationin34EMEsovertheperiod2000–2022.
2
Thepaperfocusesontheeffectofunexpecteddebtaccumulationsoneconomicgrowthandinflationinemergingeconomies.Researchontheimplicationsofdebtonoutputaremoreprevalentintheliteraturecomparedtothoseoninflation,withsomestudiesnotingnonlinearityintherelationship,wherebydebtoveracertainthresholdcanreducegrowth(Baum,Checherita-Westphal,andRother2013;Cecchetti,Mohanty,andZampolli2011;ReinhartandRogoff2010).However,thereisalackofconsensus,withotherworkfindinganegativerelationshipandnothresholds(EberhardtandPresbitero2015,PanizzaandPresbitero2014,WooandKumar2015).Morerecentworkhasfoundthatthetrajectoryofdebtmatterfortheimpactongrowth(deSoyres,Kawai,andWang2022,Chudiketal.2017).Otherworkhasfocusedonprivateandcorporatedebt,systemicrisk,andrecessions(Jordàetal.2013,BernardiniandForni2017).Asregardstheinflationaryrepercussionsofdebtshocks,thiscanbetracedbacktoSargentandWallace(1981),whofoundthatpersistentfiscaldeficitsandexcessivedebtconstrainthecentralbankfromtighteningmonetarypolicy,leadingtoamplifiedinflationexpectations.Studiespertainingtomonetarypolicycoordinationwithfiscalpolicyhavealsoshedlightontheroleoffiscalshocksoninflation,withsomepreviousworkfindingthatfiscaltighteningininflation-targetingcentralbankeconomieshelpstoreduceinflation(Cat?oandTerrones2005;deMendon?aandMachado2013;Coibion,Gorodnichenko,andWeber2021;Brandao-Marquesetal.2023).CevikandMiryugin(2023)alsofindtheextentoffiscalpolicyshocksoninflationiscloselydrivenbytheinitialleveloffiscalspace.ForEMEsinparticular,theriskofencounteringadebt-inflationtrapwasfoundforhighly-indebtedeconomies(Kwon,McFarlane,andRobinson2009).
3
Inthispaper,examiningtheeffectofdebtshocksonoutputandinflationacrossEMEs,weovercomepotentialendogeneityconcernsbycomputingaseriesofidentifiedpublicdebtshocksforeachofthe34EMEs.FollowingtheapproachbydeSoyres,Kawai,andWang(2022),weusetheforecasterrorsfromtheWorldEconomicOutlook(WEO)vintagestoidentifytheexogenousshocksinpublicdebt,whichisolatetheimpactfromthedebtvariableonly.Theestimatedpublicdebtshocksthereforemitigatetheendogeneityissuebetweenpublicdebtandothermacroeconomicvariables,includingrealGDPandinflationrate.WethenestimatetheresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetotheidentifiedpublicdebtshocksandfindthatrealGDPsignificantlydecreasesafteranunanticipatedincreaseinpublicdebtwhiletheinflationraterespondsintheoppositedirection.Theseresultsarerobusttoasetofsensitivitychecks,includingaddinglagsofinitialdebtlevelascontrolsanddroppinglagsofdependentvariables.
WealsostudywhetherfundamentalcharacteristicsacrossEMEscouldaffecttheimpactofpublicdebtshocks.Theresultssuggestthatahigherinitialdebt,atighterdomesticfinancialcondition,andalowerincomelevelcouldstrengthenthenegativeresponsesofrealGDPwhiletighterglobalfinancialconditionsdampenthenegativeimpactsofdebtshocks.Fortheinflationrate,theresponsesvarydependingoneconomic-specificcharacteristics.Wealsofindsignificantstatedependency,withEMEsfacingmoresevereeffectsduringrecessionaryperiods.Theremainderofthispaperisstructuredasfollows.Section2describesthedataandoutlinestheempiricalmethodology.Section3presentstheempiricalresultswithrobustnesschecks.Section4presentstheresultsoftheextendedanalysis.Section5concludes.
4
2.DataandEmpiricalMethodology
Inthissection,wefirstdescribethedatasourceofvariablesweuseintheempiricalanalysis.Wethendiscusstheidentificationofthepublicdebtshocks.Finally,wepresent
oureconometricframeworkusedtoproducetheempiricalresults.
2.1Data
Weuseavailableyearlydatawithanunbalancedpanelfor34EMEsspanningfrom2000to2022.1WecollectdataontherealGDPasthedomesticoutputmeasure,theyear-on-yearchangeoftheconsumerpriceindexasameasureoftheinflationrate,andtheactualandprojectedpublicdebtrelativetoitsGDP.ThedataareallfromtheWEOoftheInternationalMonetaryFund(IMF).
Astheimpactofpublicdebtonthemacroeconomycanbeaffectedbydomesticandglobalfinancialconditions,wealsoincludethefollowingtwovariablesinourempiricalanalysis.First,tomeasurethedomesticfinancialconditions,weconstructafinancialconditionindexbyaveragingthecentralbankpolicyrateand10-yeargovernmentbondyield,obtainedfromtheIMF’sInternationalFinancialStatistics.Second,weusetheVIXindexwhichstandsfortheChicagoBoardOptionsExchange(CBOE)VolatilityIndex,asameasureofglobalfinancialconditions.
1ThesampleofEMEsincludesBrazil;Bulgaria;Chile;thePeople’sRepublicofChina;Colombia;CzechRepublic;Egypt;Greece;HongKong,China;Hungary;Indonesia;Israel;theRepublicofKorea;Kuwait;Mauritius;Mexico;Malaysia;Morocco;Nigeria;Pakistan;Peru;thePhilippines;Poland;Qatar;Romania;theRussianFederation;SaudiArabia;Singapore;SouthAfrica;Taipei,China;Thailand;Ukraine;VietNam;andtheUnitedArabEmirates.Thedatastartingyearforaspecificvariablevariesacrosseconomiesduetothedataavailabilityandreliability.
5
2.2IdentificationofPublicDebtShocks
Thegoalofthispaperistoestimatethecausaleffectofpublicdebtonoutputandinflationinemergingeconomies.Assuch,wefacetheusualendogeneityissuebetweenpublicdebtandothermacroeconomicvariables,includingrealGDPandinflation.Toidentifyexogenousshocksinpublicdebt,followingdeSoyres,Kawai,andWang(2022),weusetheforecasterrorsfromvariousvintagesoftheIMFWEOpublications.Wecomputethedebtshocksindebt-to-GDPterms,withtheshockappliedonlytopublicdebtandnottoGDP,toisolatetheimpactfromthedebtvariableonly.Specifically,publicdebtshockscanbedefinedasfollows:
debtock=Δlndebt?Δlndebt,(1)
whereΔlndebtreferstotheloggrowthrateoftheactualdebt-to-GDPratioand
Δlndebt,istheloggrowthrateoftheforecasteddebt-to-actualGDPratio
projectedbyIMFanalystsinOctoberofthesameyear.Thechangebetweentheactualandprojectedpublicdebtlevelsisthusidentifiedasanexogenousshocktopublicdebtastheforecasterrorsabsentanyunanticipatedpolicychanges(e.g.,BlanchardandPerotti2002;AuerbachandGorodnichenko2012,2013;Abiad,Furceri,andTopalova2016;andFurcerietal.2018).
6
2.3EconometricMethodology
FollowingtheframeworkproposedbyJordà(2005),weusethepanellocalprojection(LP)toestimatethemodelandcalculateimpulseresponsestoexogenouspublicdebtshocks.Thebaselinemodelcanbegivenasfollows:
L
l=0
(2)
wherei=1,?Nreferstothespecificeconomyinthesample,yisthevariableof
interest(e.g.,realGDPorinflationrate),debtockistheseriesofidentifiedpublicdebt
shocks,zisavectorofcontrolvariablesincludinglaggedvaluesforyanddebtock
aswellasothercontrolvariables,andδlhisavectorofcoefficientsassociatedwiththelagsofz.Specifically,wesetL=2,thereforeweinclude2yearsoflaggedvaluesofz.Thecoefficientβhmeasurestheimpactofa1%publicdebtshocks,namelya1percentunanticipatedincreaseinthepublicdebttoGDPratio,onyathorizon?.Thus,oneconstructstheimpulseresponsesasasequenceoftheβhestimatedinaseriesofseparateregressionsforeachhorizon?.αidenoteseconomy-specificfixedeffects,
controllingforthetime-invariantcharacteristicsoftheeconomy.λrepresentsthetime
fixedeffects2.Finally,εi,t+hdenotesameanzeroerrortermcapturingothershocks.Weclusterourstandarderrorsattheeconomylevel.
WecanfurtheradapttheLPframeworktoallowfornonlinearitiesinthespecificationsthatareassociatedwithdomesticandglobalfinancialconditions.Wethereforemakethe
2ThetimefixedeffectsalsocontrolforstructuralbreaksduetotheCOVID-19pandemic.
7
responseofoutputorinflationtoapublicdebtshockalsodependentonthecontemporaneouschangeindomesticandglobalfinancialconditionsbyinteractingthepublicdebtshockwiththechangeinfinancialconditionvariables.Thespecificationisasfollows:
L
yi,t+h?yi,t-1=αZi,t-l+βhdebtock+θhFci,t×debtock+εi,t+h
l=0
(3)
whereFci,tisavariablerepresentingourfinancialconditionvariables,includingthedomesticfinancialconditionindex,andglobalfinancialconditions(measuredastheVIXindex).Therefore,βhmeasurestheresponseofoutputorinflationtothepublicdebtshockateachhorizon(year)?whenthefinancialconditionsareisolated,andβh+σθhrepresentsthetotaleffectsofpublicdebtshockswhenweconsidertheimpactoffinancialconditions.σmeasuresonepercentagechangeinthespecificfinancialconditionvariable.
WealsodivideEMEsintogroupsaccordingtotheirlevelsofinitialpublicdebts,incomeclassifications,andregionalcategorizationsandestimateseparateimpulseresponsesforeachgroup.Regardingtheestimationoflocalprojections,weincorporateadummyvariableIthattakesavalueof1forEMEswherebytheyfallwithinacertaingroupm∈M.FollowingCloyneetal.(2023),weextendthelocalprojectionasfollows:
yi,t+h?yi,t-1=α+λ+∈MI[Σl0δ,lZi,t-l+βdebt,ock+θFci,t×debt,ock]+εi,t+h(4)
wherethenotationisasinequation3.
8
3.EmpiricalResults
3.1BaselineResults
Figure1showstheestimatedimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetopublicdebtshocks,basedonthelinearmodelofequation2.Thesolidlineineachgraphrepresentstheestimatedimpulseresponsesinpercentageoverthefollowing5yearstoa1%positivepublicdebtshock,namelya1%unanticipatedincreaseinthepublicdebttoGDPratio.Theshadedarearepresents68%(dark)and90%(light)confidencebands.
Figure1:ResponseofRealGDPandInflationtoPublicDebtshocks,Baseline
GDP=grossdomesticproduct.
Notes:ThefigureplotstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebt
shock.Shadedareasrepresent68%and90%confidencebands.Source:Authors’estimates.
TheimpulseresponsesindicatethatrealGDPdecreasesafteranunanticipatedincreaseinpublicdebtwhiletheinflationraterespondspositivelytodebtshocks.3Followingapositivepublicdebtshock,thelevelofrealGDPdecreaseswithamaximumimpactof–0.015%percentaround2yearsaftertheshock.TheestimatedresultisinlinewiththeliteraturethatalsoshowsanegativeimpactofpublicdebtshocksonrealGDP
3Ourresultsalsoshowthata1%debtshockalsotriggersasignificantpositiveresponseindebtitselfbyaround0.03%to0.07%withinthefirstyear.
9
(e.g.,ReinhartandRogoff2010;WooandKumar2015;deSoyres,Kawai,andWang
2022).Onthecontrary,publicdebtshockshaveapositiveimpactontheinflationrate.4Anunexpectedincreaseinpublicdebtisassociatedwithapersistentincreaseintheinflationrate,whichisbroadlyconsistentwithCat?oandTerrones(2005)whofindastrongpositiveassociationbetweendeficitsandinflationamonghigh-inflationand
developingeconomies.
3.2Robustness
3.2.1AddingLagsofInitialDebtLevelasControls
Tochecktherobustnessofourbaselineresults,weaddtwolagsoftheinitialdebt-to-GDPratioasadditionalcontrols.Figure2reportstheestimatedimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebtshock,addinglagsofinitialdebtlevelasadditionalcontrols.TheresultsshowthatrealGDPdecreasespersistentlyandsignificantlyaftertheshockwhiletheinflationraterespondspositively,broadlyconsistentwithourbaselineestimates.
4Whilethereisastrongunderlyingeconomicrationaleforincludingtimedummiesinthebaseline(i.e.,tocontrolforanytrendbehaviorintheforecasterrors),theresultsexcludingthetimedummiesarenotmateriallydifferent.Globaldebtshocksindeedwillbereflectedwithvariationacrossdomesticdebtdynamics.Thebaselineapproachinidentifyingthedebtshocksusingforecasterrorsremainsconsistentattheeconomyleveltherefore,eveninthepresenceofglobaldebtshocks.Theinclusionoftimedummiesfurthercontrolsforanyresidualtrendbehaviorthatcouldbedrivenbyglobalfactors.Nonetheless,theresultsthatexcludethetimedummiesdonotsignificantlychangethebaselineresults.Heterogeneitiesintimedummyestimatesacrossalternativecategoriesofeconomies,suchashighversuslowincome,alsodonotsignificantlychangethebaselineresults.
10
Figure2:ResponseofRealGDPandInflationtoPublicDebtShocks,AddingLagsofInitialDebtLevels
GDP=grossdomesticproduct.
Notes:ThefigureplotstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebtshock.Shadedareasrepresent68%and90%confidencebands.
Source:Authors’estimates.
3.2.2DroppingLagsofDependentVariables
Thusfar,wehavefollowedtheliteratureonstandardlocalprojections,addinglaggeddependentvariablesascontrols.Ontheotherhand,onemaybeconcernedthatendogeneityissuesmayariseifthereisacorrelationbetweenthelagsofthedependentvariablesandtheexcludedlagssubsumedintheerrorterm(e.g.,Nickell-bias).Forthisreason,wenowdropthelaggeddependentvariablestofurthersubstantiateourbaselineestimates.Figure3reportstheestimatedimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebtshock,droppinglaggeddependentvariables.TheresultsshowthatrealGDPdecreasessignificantlyaftertheshockwhiletheinflationraterespondspositively,furtherindicatingtherobustnessofourbaselineestimates.
11
Figure3:ResponseofRealGDPandInflationtoPublicDebtShocks,DroppingLaggedDependentVariables
GDP=grossdomesticproduct.
Notes:ThefigureplotstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebtshock.Shadedareasrepresent68%and90%confidencebands.
Source:Authors’estimates.
3.2.3AlternativePublicDebtShockMeasurements
Tofurtherstrengthenthecasethattheforecasterrorscanberegardedasexogenousdebtshocks(evenpotentiallycapturinginflationorgrowthsurprises),wefollowthemethodologyintheOctober2017IMFWEOandMagudandPienknagura(2022)byorthogonalizingthedebtshocks.WeregressthedebtforecasterrorsonforecasterrorsofrealGDPgrowthandinflation,includingasetofeconomy-fixedeffects.Theresidualsfromtheseregressionsarethenusedasouralternativedebtshocks.Usingthealternativedebtshockmeasurement,theresults(Figure4)indicatethatourbenchmarkestimatesarequantitativelyandqualitativelyrobusttoalternativedebtshocks.
12
Figure4:ResponseofRealGDPandInflationtoPublicDebtShocks,AlternativePublicDebtShockMeasurements
GDP=grossdomesticproduct.
Notes:ThefigureplotstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebt
shock.Shadedareasrepresent68%and90%confidencebands.Source:Authors’estimates.
4.Extensions
4.1ImpulseResponsesConditioningonInitialDebtLevels
Sofar,wehaveexaminedtheimpactofpublicdebtshocksonoutputandinflationirrespectiveofinitialdebtlevels.Toexploretheextenttowhichtheex-antelevelofpublicdebtmattersinshapingtheresponsedynamicstothedebtshock,wefocusonthedifferenceintheimpactofthedebtshockonEMEswithdifferentinitialpublicdebtlevels.Specifically,weseparateoursampleEMEsintotwogroups:highandlowinitiallevelofpublicdebt,usingasathresholdthemedianofoursample(41.07%).Figure5illustratestheresponseofrealGDPandinflationforEMEswithlowandhighinitiallevelsofpublicdebt.Thefigureshowsthatforeconomiesinthehighdebtgroup,thenegativeimpactoftheunanticipatedpublicdebtincreaseonrealGDPismuchstrongerthanthebaselinecase,leadingtoasignificant–0.33%decreaseinrealGDParound1yearaftertheshock.
13
Bycontrast,high-debteconomiesexperienceasignificantdecreaseininflationrateinresponsetoapublicdebtrise,indicatingthatdebtsustainabilityconcernsmayfurtherweakentheaggregatedemandforEMEswithhighdebtlevels.Forthelow-debteconomies,wefindthattheresponsesofrealGDPandinflationaresimilarwiththebaselinecasewhiletheimpactofpublicdebtincreaseisslightlyweakerintheshortterm.5
Inthecaseofhigh-debteconomies,debtshocksineconomieswheredebtisalreadyelevatedcantriggernegativeaggregatedemandeffects(Mian,Straub,andSufi2022).Thechannelworksthroughaweakeninginthecredibilityoffiscalpolicy,andlowerconsumptionduetoresultingnegativewealtheffects.Inparticular,alackofcredibilitybyagentsinfiscalpolicycanleadtoanticipatedrisesintaxationlateron,triggeringnegativedemandeffects,andlowerinflation(MontesanddeHollandaLima2022).
Figure5:ResponseofRealGDPandInflationtoPublicDebtShocks,byInitialDebtLevels
(a)RealGDP
Continuedonthenextpage
5Notethatforcomparativepurposesandforclarityonthedifferencesinimpactbymagnitude,aconsistentscaleisusedforlowversushighdebtgroups.
14
(b)Inflation
GDP=grossdomesticproduct.
Notes:ThefigureplotstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebtshock.Shadedareasrepresent68%and90%confidencebands.
Source:Authors’estimates.
4.2ImpulseResponsesConditioningonDomesticFinancialConditions
Wetestifaneconomy’sdomesticfinancialconditionsaffecttheimpactofpublicdebtshocksonoutputandinflation.Specifically,weinteractthepublicdebtshockwithourconstructedfinancialconditionindexasinequation3.Figure6showstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetopositivepublicdebtshocksdependingondomesticfinancialconditions.Ourresultsshowthattighterdomesticfinancialconditionsfurtherstrengthentheimpactofanunanticipatedincreaseinpublicdebtontheoutput.ThelevelofrealGDPdecreasesbyabout–0.38%1yearaftertheshockanddropspersistentlyafter3years.Regardingtheinflationrate,theoverallresponsestoapositivepublicdebtshockaremoremutedandshowoppositesignscomparedtothebaseline.
15
Figure6:ResponseofRealGDPandInflationtoPublicDebtShocks,ConditioningonDomesticFinancialConditions
GDP=grossdomesticproduct.
Notes:ThefigureplotstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebt
shock.Shadedareasrepresent68%and90%confidencebands.Source:Authors’estimates.
4.3ImpulseResponsesConditioningonGlobalFinancialConditions
WefurtherexaminewhetherglobalfinancialconditionsmayimpacttheeffectofdebtincreasebyinteractingthepublicdebtshockwiththeVIXindex,basedonequation3.Figure7showstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetopositivepublicdebtshocksconditioningonglobalfinancialconditions.Ourresultsshowthattheimpactofpublicdebtshocksonoutputandinflationissomewhatweakerwithtighterglobalfinancialconditions.AlthoughthelevelofrealGDPdecreasesbyabout–0.11%1yearaftertheshock,thenegativeresponsesdisappearandbecomestatisticallyinsignificantafter2years.Similarly,whiletheinflationrateincreasesbyabout0.1percentagepointsrightafterthepositivepublicdebtshock,theoverallresponsesaremoremutedcomparedtothebaseline.
16
Figure7:ResponseofRealGDPandInflationtoPublicDebtShocks,ConditioningonGlobalFinancialConditions
GDP=grossdomesticproduct.
Notes:ThefigureplotstheimpulseresponsesofrealGDPandinflationratetoa1%positivepublicdebtshock.Shadedareasrepresent68%and90%confidencebands.
Source:Authors’estimates.
4.4ImpulseResponsesConditioningonIncomeLevels
Toanalyzehowtheincomelevelaffectstheimpactofanunanticipatedincreaseinpublicdebt,wedivideou
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 會(huì)議贊助協(xié)議合同范本
- 農(nóng)村魚塘轉(zhuǎn)讓合同范本
- 加盟合同范本烤鴨
- 勞務(wù)合同范本拼音寫
- 上海理財(cái)合同范本
- 包子店員工合同范本
- 勞務(wù)補(bǔ)助合同范本
- 修補(bǔ)圍網(wǎng)合同范本
- 公積金擔(dān)保合同范本
- 出租醫(yī)療服務(wù)合同范本
- 英語-時(shí)文閱讀-7年級(jí)(8篇)
- 數(shù)據(jù)挖掘(第2版)全套教學(xué)課件
- 產(chǎn)學(xué)研融合創(chuàng)新合作機(jī)制
- 分揀員工作管理制度
- 胃早癌-經(jīng)典課件
- 酒店管理概論 課件 第1章 酒店管理概述
- 網(wǎng)絡(luò)分布式系統(tǒng)架構(gòu)
- 幕墻工安全技術(shù)交底
- 集裝箱七點(diǎn)檢查表
- 創(chuàng)傷傷口包扎術(shù)(加壓包扎止血法)技術(shù)操作考核評(píng)分標(biāo)準(zhǔn)
- 籃球場(chǎng)改造工程投標(biāo)方案(技術(shù)方案)
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論