法學(xué)外文翻譯_第1頁
法學(xué)外文翻譯_第2頁
法學(xué)外文翻譯_第3頁
法學(xué)外文翻譯_第4頁
全文預(yù)覽已結(jié)束

下載本文檔

版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)

文檔簡介

1、the breach of contract in french law: between safety of expectations and efficiencypierre garellofaculte deconomie applique, universite de droit, deconimie et des sciences d aix-marseille,3 avenue robert schuman, aix-en-provence 13628, franceaccepted 20 august 20021. introduction: which path will le

2、ad us to a better understanding of french contract law?contracts are marvellous tools to help us to live in a world of uncertainty. they allow us to project ourselves into an unknowable future, to invest. lawyers who have inspired the french civil law and contributed to its evolution, as well as mos

3、t lawyers in the world, have clearly perceived the necessity to protect that institution. “the contract is, as far as the individual is concerned, the best forecasting instrument generating legal security, and the favored path to freedom and responsibility that is necessary for the flourishing of hu

4、man beings in a society.”1contracts are far from miraculous tools, however. if they make life easier, they do not necessarily make life easy. as the future unfolds, one or both contracting parties may be tempted, or compelled, to break his or her promise. but, the mere fact that the contract is runn

5、ing into difficulties does not force the law to do something!2 it is only when one of the parties does not perform that the law (the court, the legislation), backed with coercive power, has to give an opinion, to decide the case. in order to do so some principles, or theories, are required to reach

6、a judgment as to what is the best thing to do.the present study of the french contract law is based on the premise that, from a law and economics point of view, there exists basically two possible ways to address this concern: the first approach requires that whenever a problem arises, an assessment

7、 be made of all costs and benefits incurred by the parties. in other words, one must attempt to evaluate in a sufficiently precise way the consequences of the court decisionor of the rule of law under considerationfor both parties as well as for third parties (including potential future contractors)

8、. the lawthenand more precisely here, contract lawshould aim primarily at providing the right incentives to contracting parties, where by “right incentives” one means incentives to behave in such a way that the difference between social benefits and social costs be maximized. it will be argued below

9、 that french contract law sometimes follows this approach.the second possible attitude looks, apparently, pretty much like the first. the guiding principle is again that the law should provide to members of the society the right incentives. but one must immediately add that the judgeor the legislato

10、r, or the expertis not in a position to evaluate and compare the social costs and benefits of alternative rules of law. he or she just does not know enough. one does not know, for instance, all the effects of a rule that would allow one party to breach a contract, without the consent of the other pa

11、rty. indeed, even if the victim of the breach is promised a fair compensation, allowing such a rule globally might have a negative effect on the very purpose of the institution, which is to reduce uncertainty. as a consequence, the law should adopt a goal less ambitious than the maximization of soci

12、al well being. that goal could be “to protect contracts,” or, in other terms, to create a set of incentives that lead individuals to feel confident that their legitimate expectations will be fulfilled.as pointed out, those two attitudes may appear the same, differing just in degree. the first one as

13、sumes more knowledge on the part of lawyers and legislators than the second. however, when it comes to practical decision-making, differences turn out to be important, because the more knowledgeable you think you are, the stronger will be the incentive to regulate the contract, and the lower will be

14、 the respect for tradition and customs on which daily expectations are based.the two approaches outlined above are well known to economists. the first one is the so-called “mainstream” (paretian) approach and underlines most of the existing economic analysis of law.3 the second one, stressing the pr

15、oblem of knowledge, is far less developed.4 we will call it the “safety-of-expectations approach,” or the austrian approach to law and economics, because it can be found primarily in thework of the austrian school of economic thought, and especially in hayeks studies.“the rationale,” says hayek, “of

16、 securing to each individual a known range within which he can decide on his actions is to enable him to make the fullest use of his knowledge, especially of his concrete and often unique knowledge of the particular circumstances of time and place. the law tells him what facts he may count on and th

17、ereby extends the range within which he can predict the consequences of his actions. at the same time it tells him what possible consequences of his actions he must take into account or what he will be held responsible for.”5the reason why these two approaches are mentioned at the outset is that, wh

18、en one studies french contract law, it is difficult to reconcile all of it with a single approach. true, the mainstream, neoclassical approach, based on the assumption that rules be chosen that maximize social wealth (or, at other times, that lead to a pareto-efficient outcome), can help us to under

19、stand an important part of that body of law. but, as will be shown, certain french doctrines cannot be reconciled with neither a paretian approach, nor a wealth maximizing approach. in some instances, the lawseems to be more concerned with the safety of expectations.in the next two sections we will

20、examine the main doctrines and rules of french contract law trying to identify those that are compatible with both principles and those that are compatible with only one. if none of those sets are empty, it will mean that the french law of contract is not totally coherent; it cannot be brought under

21、 a unique unifying principle of explanation. the next natural questionwould then be whether french lawismoving towards one principle and away from the other. however, this paper will not address this question.the paper is organized in two parts. indeed, for reasons briefly mentioned above, it is imp

22、ortant to underline in a first part the many things the law does in order to avoid breach of contract: what can be done in order to save a contract when the parties are having difficulties performing, and what is forbidden? the second part deals directly with the breach of contract. it will be shown

23、 that french law differs in some important respects from other contract laws.2.3. 待添加的隱藏文字內(nèi)容1saving the contract6we will study the various attempts to “save” the contract by looking first at the conditions for invalidity (section 2.1), then at the various possibilities left to the judge to interpret

24、 the terms of the contract (section 2.2) and end with the study of the cases where the judge is authorized to change the terms of the contract (section 2.3).2.1. invalid contractsone way to save the contract is to prove that there was no valid contract in the first place! formation defenses as defin

25、ed in the french law are roughly identical to those found in the contract laws of other countries. the main defenses are: incompetency (incapacit), mistakes (erreur), fraud (dol), duress (violence), absence of cause (reminding us of the doctrine of consideration in the bargaining theory), failure to

26、 disclose information, lsion (a defense close to unconscionability),7 or, may be more specific to french law, a conflict between the private agreement and ordre public, i.e. public policy, or “l(fā)aw and order” (see art. 6 and 1134 of the french civil code, henceforth c.civ.). in all these instances, a

27、n action may be taken for annulment of the contract, the judge being the only one entitled to invalidate a contract.but, what exactly is meant by invalidity in the french law? what are the consequences? the french law distinguishes between absolute invalidity (nullit absolue) and relative invalidity

28、 (nullit relative). the first category includes all the contracts that are against what is called ordre public de direction, that is to say, contracts that violate a public policy judged to be beneficial to the society as a whole and not only to those individuals involved in that particular contract

29、. for such contracts nothing can be done and complete nullity cannot be avoided. the second category is made of contracts that violate the ordre public de protection, that is, contracts in which one party does not respect a public policy designed to protect weaker parties. in those circumstances, th

30、e victim who the law is trying to protect may choose to let the contract stand after modifications to the contract.8in both cases, however, the result is as if the contract had never existed, and retroactivity with restitution is the general principle: one is supposed to go back to the situation tha

31、t prevailed before the contract was created: the status quo ante. parties are relieved of their obligations, and damages can no longer be awarded, but it is still possible to bring a tort law action.9from an economic point of view, most of the formation defenses mentioned have already been analyzed

32、in various places, the bottom line being: any contract that is not voluntary must be considered as invalid. one can see however that, from a strictly paretian point of view, it is not clear that all involuntary contractse.g. contracts relying on a mistakewill always be dominated by the situation pre

33、vailing before the contract. if one chooses the hayekian, safety-of-expectations point of view, such a dilemma is less likely to occur to the extent that people expect transactions to be voluntary. consequently, any involuntary transaction violates some “l(fā)egitimate expectations.” before leaving the

34、topic of nullity, two interesting facts deserve attention. first, it must be pointed out that exceptions exist to the general principle of retroactivity with restitution. in particular, if the contract is null due to the deliberate action of one of the parties (e.g. in the case of fraud), the principle is softened; the victim sometimes will not have to return the object, or the payment. the action for annulment can even be rejected by the judge if this favors the victim. finally, be

溫馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
  • 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
  • 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
  • 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
  • 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。

評論

0/150

提交評論